Oxford Martin School logo

Technology over the long run: zoom out to see how dramatically the world can change within a lifetime

It is easy to underestimate how much the world can change within a lifetime. considering how dramatically the world has changed can help us see how different the world could be in a few years or decades..

Technology can change the world in ways that are unimaginable until they happen. Switching on an electric light would have been unimaginable for our medieval ancestors. In their childhood, our grandparents would have struggled to imagine a world connected by smartphones and the Internet.

Similarly, it is hard for us to imagine the arrival of all those technologies that will fundamentally change the world we are used to.

We can remind ourselves that our own future might look very different from the world today by looking back at how rapidly technology has changed our world in the past. That’s what this article is about.

One insight I take away from this long-term perspective is how unusual our time is. Technological change was extremely slow in the past – the technologies that our ancestors got used to in their childhood were still central to their lives in their old age. In stark contrast to those days, we live in a time of extraordinarily fast technological change. For recent generations, it was common for technologies that were unimaginable in their youth to become common later in life.

The long-run perspective on technological change

The big visualization offers a long-term perspective on the history of technology. 1

The timeline begins at the center of the spiral. The first use of stone tools, 3.4 million years ago, marks the beginning of this history of technology. 2 Each turn of the spiral represents 200,000 years of history. It took 2.4 million years – 12 turns of the spiral – for our ancestors to control fire and use it for cooking. 3

To be able to visualize the inventions in the more recent past – the last 12,000 years – I had to unroll the spiral. I needed more space to be able to show when agriculture, writing, and the wheel were invented. During this period, technological change was faster, but it was still relatively slow: several thousand years passed between each of these three inventions.

From 1800 onwards, I stretched out the timeline even further to show the many major inventions that rapidly followed one after the other.

The long-term perspective that this chart provides makes it clear just how unusually fast technological change is in our time.

You can use this visualization to see how technology developed in particular domains. Follow, for example, the history of communication: from writing to paper, to the printing press, to the telegraph, the telephone, the radio, all the way to the Internet and smartphones.

Or follow the rapid development of human flight. In 1903, the Wright brothers took the first flight in human history (they were in the air for less than a minute), and just 66 years later, we landed on the moon. Many people saw both within their lifetimes: the first plane and the moon landing.

This large visualization also highlights the wide range of technology’s impact on our lives. It includes extraordinarily beneficial innovations, such as the vaccine that allowed humanity to eradicate smallpox , and it includes terrible innovations, like the nuclear bombs that endanger the lives of all of us .

What will the next decades bring?

The red timeline reaches up to the present and then continues in green into the future. Many children born today, even without further increases in life expectancy, will live well into the 22nd century.

New vaccines, progress in clean, low-carbon energy, better cancer treatments – a range of future innovations could very much improve our living conditions and the environment around us. But, as I argue in a series of articles , there is one technology that could even more profoundly change our world: artificial intelligence (AI).

One reason why artificial intelligence is such an important innovation is that intelligence is the main driver of innovation itself. This fast-paced technological change could speed up even more if it’s driven not only by humanity’s intelligence but also by artificial intelligence. If this happens, the change currently stretched out over decades might happen within a very brief time span of just a year. Possibly even faster. 4

I think AI technology could have a fundamentally transformative impact on our world. In many ways, it is already changing our world, as I documented in this companion article . As this technology becomes more capable in the years and decades to come, it can give immense power to those who control it (and it poses the risk that it could escape our control entirely).

Such systems might seem hard to imagine today, but AI technology is advancing quickly. Many AI experts believe there is a real chance that human-level artificial intelligence will be developed within the next decades, as I documented in this article .

legacy-wordpress-upload

Technology will continue to change the world – we should all make sure that it changes it for the better

What is familiar to us today – photography, the radio, antibiotics, the Internet, or the International Space Station circling our planet – was unimaginable to our ancestors just a few generations ago. If your great-great-great grandparents could spend a week with you, they would be blown away by your everyday life.

What I take away from this history is that I will likely see technologies in my lifetime that appear unimaginable to me today.

In addition to this trend towards increasingly rapid innovation, there is a second long-run trend. Technology has become increasingly powerful. While our ancestors wielded stone tools, we are building globe-spanning AI systems and technologies that can edit our genes.

Because of the immense power that technology gives those who control it, there is little that is as important as the question of which technologies get developed during our lifetimes. Therefore, I think it is a mistake to leave the question about the future of technology to the technologists. Which technologies are controlled by whom is one of the most important political questions of our time because of the enormous power these technologies convey to those who control them.

We all should strive to gain the knowledge we need to contribute to an intelligent debate about the world we want to live in. To a large part, this means gaining knowledge and wisdom on the question of which technologies we want.

Acknowledgments: I would like to thank my colleagues Hannah Ritchie, Bastian Herre, Natasha Ahuja, Edouard Mathieu, Daniel Bachler, Charlie Giattino, and Pablo Rosado for their helpful comments on drafts of this essay and the visualization. Thanks also to Lizka Vaintrob and Ben Clifford for the conversation that initiated this visualization.

Appendix: About the choice of visualization in this article

The recent speed of technological change makes it difficult to picture the history of technology in one visualization. When you visualize this development on a linear timeline, then most of the timeline is almost empty, while all the action is crammed into the right corner:

Linear version of the spiral chart

In my large visualization here, I tried to avoid this problem and instead show the long history of technology in a way that lets you see when each technological breakthrough happened and how, within the last millennia, there was a continuous acceleration of technological change.

The recent speed of technological change makes it difficult to picture the history of technology in one visualization. In the appendix, I show how this would look if it were linear.

It is, of course, difficult to assess when exactly the first stone tools were used.

The research by McPherron et al. (2010) suggested that it was at least 3.39 million years ago. This is based on two fossilized bones found in Dikika in Ethiopia, which showed “stone-tool cut marks for flesh removal and percussion marks for marrow access”. These marks were interpreted as being caused by meat consumption and provide the first evidence that one of our ancestors, Australopithecus afarensis, used stone tools.

The research by Harmand et al. (2015) provided evidence for stone tool use in today’s Kenya 3.3 million years ago.

References:

McPherron et al. (2010) – Evidence for stone-tool-assisted consumption of animal tissues before 3.39 million years ago at Dikika, Ethiopia . Published in Nature.

Harmand et al. (2015) – 3.3-million-year-old stone tools from Lomekwi 3, West Turkana, Kenya . Published in Nature.

Evidence for controlled fire use approximately 1 million years ago is provided by Berna et al. (2012) Microstratigraphic evidence of in situ fire in the Acheulean strata of Wonderwerk Cave, Northern Cape province, South Africa , published in PNAS.

The authors write: “The ability to control fire was a crucial turning point in human evolution, but the question of when hominins first developed this ability still remains. Here we show that micromorphological and Fourier transform infrared microspectroscopy (mFTIR) analyses of intact sediments at the site of Wonderwerk Cave, Northern Cape province, South Africa, provide unambiguous evidence—in the form of burned bone and ashed plant remains—that burning took place in the cave during the early Acheulean occupation, approximately 1.0 Ma. To the best of our knowledge, this is the earliest secure evidence for burning in an archaeological context.”

This is what authors like Holden Karnofsky called ‘Process for Automating Scientific and Technological Advancement’ or PASTA. Some recent developments go in this direction: DeepMind’s AlphaFold helped to make progress on one of the large problems in biology, and they have also developed an AI system that finds new algorithms that are relevant to building a more powerful AI.

Cite this work

Our articles and data visualizations rely on work from many different people and organizations. When citing this article, please also cite the underlying data sources. This article can be cited as:

BibTeX citation

Reuse this work freely

All visualizations, data, and code produced by Our World in Data are completely open access under the Creative Commons BY license . You have the permission to use, distribute, and reproduce these in any medium, provided the source and authors are credited.

The data produced by third parties and made available by Our World in Data is subject to the license terms from the original third-party authors. We will always indicate the original source of the data in our documentation, so you should always check the license of any such third-party data before use and redistribution.

All of our charts can be embedded in any site.

Our World in Data is free and accessible for everyone.

Help us do this work by making a donation.

Issue Cover

  • Previous Article
  • Next Article

Promises and Pitfalls of Technology

Politics and privacy, private-sector influence and big tech, state competition and conflict, author biography, how is technology changing the world, and how should the world change technology.

[email protected]

  • Split-Screen
  • Article contents
  • Figures & tables
  • Supplementary Data
  • Peer Review
  • Open the PDF for in another window
  • Guest Access
  • Get Permissions
  • Cite Icon Cite
  • Search Site

Josephine Wolff; How Is Technology Changing the World, and How Should the World Change Technology?. Global Perspectives 1 February 2021; 2 (1): 27353. doi: https://doi.org/10.1525/gp.2021.27353

Download citation file:

  • Ris (Zotero)
  • Reference Manager

Technologies are becoming increasingly complicated and increasingly interconnected. Cars, airplanes, medical devices, financial transactions, and electricity systems all rely on more computer software than they ever have before, making them seem both harder to understand and, in some cases, harder to control. Government and corporate surveillance of individuals and information processing relies largely on digital technologies and artificial intelligence, and therefore involves less human-to-human contact than ever before and more opportunities for biases to be embedded and codified in our technological systems in ways we may not even be able to identify or recognize. Bioengineering advances are opening up new terrain for challenging philosophical, political, and economic questions regarding human-natural relations. Additionally, the management of these large and small devices and systems is increasingly done through the cloud, so that control over them is both very remote and removed from direct human or social control. The study of how to make technologies like artificial intelligence or the Internet of Things “explainable” has become its own area of research because it is so difficult to understand how they work or what is at fault when something goes wrong (Gunning and Aha 2019) .

This growing complexity makes it more difficult than ever—and more imperative than ever—for scholars to probe how technological advancements are altering life around the world in both positive and negative ways and what social, political, and legal tools are needed to help shape the development and design of technology in beneficial directions. This can seem like an impossible task in light of the rapid pace of technological change and the sense that its continued advancement is inevitable, but many countries around the world are only just beginning to take significant steps toward regulating computer technologies and are still in the process of radically rethinking the rules governing global data flows and exchange of technology across borders.

These are exciting times not just for technological development but also for technology policy—our technologies may be more advanced and complicated than ever but so, too, are our understandings of how they can best be leveraged, protected, and even constrained. The structures of technological systems as determined largely by government and institutional policies and those structures have tremendous implications for social organization and agency, ranging from open source, open systems that are highly distributed and decentralized, to those that are tightly controlled and closed, structured according to stricter and more hierarchical models. And just as our understanding of the governance of technology is developing in new and interesting ways, so, too, is our understanding of the social, cultural, environmental, and political dimensions of emerging technologies. We are realizing both the challenges and the importance of mapping out the full range of ways that technology is changing our society, what we want those changes to look like, and what tools we have to try to influence and guide those shifts.

Technology can be a source of tremendous optimism. It can help overcome some of the greatest challenges our society faces, including climate change, famine, and disease. For those who believe in the power of innovation and the promise of creative destruction to advance economic development and lead to better quality of life, technology is a vital economic driver (Schumpeter 1942) . But it can also be a tool of tremendous fear and oppression, embedding biases in automated decision-making processes and information-processing algorithms, exacerbating economic and social inequalities within and between countries to a staggering degree, or creating new weapons and avenues for attack unlike any we have had to face in the past. Scholars have even contended that the emergence of the term technology in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries marked a shift from viewing individual pieces of machinery as a means to achieving political and social progress to the more dangerous, or hazardous, view that larger-scale, more complex technological systems were a semiautonomous form of progress in and of themselves (Marx 2010) . More recently, technologists have sharply criticized what they view as a wave of new Luddites, people intent on slowing the development of technology and turning back the clock on innovation as a means of mitigating the societal impacts of technological change (Marlowe 1970) .

At the heart of fights over new technologies and their resulting global changes are often two conflicting visions of technology: a fundamentally optimistic one that believes humans use it as a tool to achieve greater goals, and a fundamentally pessimistic one that holds that technological systems have reached a point beyond our control. Technology philosophers have argued that neither of these views is wholly accurate and that a purely optimistic or pessimistic view of technology is insufficient to capture the nuances and complexity of our relationship to technology (Oberdiek and Tiles 1995) . Understanding technology and how we can make better decisions about designing, deploying, and refining it requires capturing that nuance and complexity through in-depth analysis of the impacts of different technological advancements and the ways they have played out in all their complicated and controversial messiness across the world.

These impacts are often unpredictable as technologies are adopted in new contexts and come to be used in ways that sometimes diverge significantly from the use cases envisioned by their designers. The internet, designed to help transmit information between computer networks, became a crucial vehicle for commerce, introducing unexpected avenues for crime and financial fraud. Social media platforms like Facebook and Twitter, designed to connect friends and families through sharing photographs and life updates, became focal points of election controversies and political influence. Cryptocurrencies, originally intended as a means of decentralized digital cash, have become a significant environmental hazard as more and more computing resources are devoted to mining these forms of virtual money. One of the crucial challenges in this area is therefore recognizing, documenting, and even anticipating some of these unexpected consequences and providing mechanisms to technologists for how to think through the impacts of their work, as well as possible other paths to different outcomes (Verbeek 2006) . And just as technological innovations can cause unexpected harm, they can also bring about extraordinary benefits—new vaccines and medicines to address global pandemics and save thousands of lives, new sources of energy that can drastically reduce emissions and help combat climate change, new modes of education that can reach people who would otherwise have no access to schooling. Regulating technology therefore requires a careful balance of mitigating risks without overly restricting potentially beneficial innovations.

Nations around the world have taken very different approaches to governing emerging technologies and have adopted a range of different technologies themselves in pursuit of more modern governance structures and processes (Braman 2009) . In Europe, the precautionary principle has guided much more anticipatory regulation aimed at addressing the risks presented by technologies even before they are fully realized. For instance, the European Union’s General Data Protection Regulation focuses on the responsibilities of data controllers and processors to provide individuals with access to their data and information about how that data is being used not just as a means of addressing existing security and privacy threats, such as data breaches, but also to protect against future developments and uses of that data for artificial intelligence and automated decision-making purposes. In Germany, Technische Überwachungsvereine, or TÜVs, perform regular tests and inspections of technological systems to assess and minimize risks over time, as the tech landscape evolves. In the United States, by contrast, there is much greater reliance on litigation and liability regimes to address safety and security failings after-the-fact. These different approaches reflect not just the different legal and regulatory mechanisms and philosophies of different nations but also the different ways those nations prioritize rapid development of the technology industry versus safety, security, and individual control. Typically, governance innovations move much more slowly than technological innovations, and regulations can lag years, or even decades, behind the technologies they aim to govern.

In addition to this varied set of national regulatory approaches, a variety of international and nongovernmental organizations also contribute to the process of developing standards, rules, and norms for new technologies, including the International Organization for Standardization­ and the International Telecommunication Union. These multilateral and NGO actors play an especially important role in trying to define appropriate boundaries for the use of new technologies by governments as instruments of control for the state.

At the same time that policymakers are under scrutiny both for their decisions about how to regulate technology as well as their decisions about how and when to adopt technologies like facial recognition themselves, technology firms and designers have also come under increasing criticism. Growing recognition that the design of technologies can have far-reaching social and political implications means that there is more pressure on technologists to take into consideration the consequences of their decisions early on in the design process (Vincenti 1993; Winner 1980) . The question of how technologists should incorporate these social dimensions into their design and development processes is an old one, and debate on these issues dates back to the 1970s, but it remains an urgent and often overlooked part of the puzzle because so many of the supposedly systematic mechanisms for assessing the impacts of new technologies in both the private and public sectors are primarily bureaucratic, symbolic processes rather than carrying any real weight or influence.

Technologists are often ill-equipped or unwilling to respond to the sorts of social problems that their creations have—often unwittingly—exacerbated, and instead point to governments and lawmakers to address those problems (Zuckerberg 2019) . But governments often have few incentives to engage in this area. This is because setting clear standards and rules for an ever-evolving technological landscape can be extremely challenging, because enforcement of those rules can be a significant undertaking requiring considerable expertise, and because the tech sector is a major source of jobs and revenue for many countries that may fear losing those benefits if they constrain companies too much. This indicates not just a need for clearer incentives and better policies for both private- and public-sector entities but also a need for new mechanisms whereby the technology development and design process can be influenced and assessed by people with a wider range of experiences and expertise. If we want technologies to be designed with an eye to their impacts, who is responsible for predicting, measuring, and mitigating those impacts throughout the design process? Involving policymakers in that process in a more meaningful way will also require training them to have the analytic and technical capacity to more fully engage with technologists and understand more fully the implications of their decisions.

At the same time that tech companies seem unwilling or unable to rein in their creations, many also fear they wield too much power, in some cases all but replacing governments and international organizations in their ability to make decisions that affect millions of people worldwide and control access to information, platforms, and audiences (Kilovaty 2020) . Regulators around the world have begun considering whether some of these companies have become so powerful that they violate the tenets of antitrust laws, but it can be difficult for governments to identify exactly what those violations are, especially in the context of an industry where the largest players often provide their customers with free services. And the platforms and services developed by tech companies are often wielded most powerfully and dangerously not directly by their private-sector creators and operators but instead by states themselves for widespread misinformation campaigns that serve political purposes (Nye 2018) .

Since the largest private entities in the tech sector operate in many countries, they are often better poised to implement global changes to the technological ecosystem than individual states or regulatory bodies, creating new challenges to existing governance structures and hierarchies. Just as it can be challenging to provide oversight for government use of technologies, so, too, oversight of the biggest tech companies, which have more resources, reach, and power than many nations, can prove to be a daunting task. The rise of network forms of organization and the growing gig economy have added to these challenges, making it even harder for regulators to fully address the breadth of these companies’ operations (Powell 1990) . The private-public partnerships that have emerged around energy, transportation, medical, and cyber technologies further complicate this picture, blurring the line between the public and private sectors and raising critical questions about the role of each in providing critical infrastructure, health care, and security. How can and should private tech companies operating in these different sectors be governed, and what types of influence do they exert over regulators? How feasible are different policy proposals aimed at technological innovation, and what potential unintended consequences might they have?

Conflict between countries has also spilled over significantly into the private sector in recent years, most notably in the case of tensions between the United States and China over which technologies developed in each country will be permitted by the other and which will be purchased by other customers, outside those two countries. Countries competing to develop the best technology is not a new phenomenon, but the current conflicts have major international ramifications and will influence the infrastructure that is installed and used around the world for years to come. Untangling the different factors that feed into these tussles as well as whom they benefit and whom they leave at a disadvantage is crucial for understanding how governments can most effectively foster technological innovation and invention domestically as well as the global consequences of those efforts. As much of the world is forced to choose between buying technology from the United States or from China, how should we understand the long-term impacts of those choices and the options available to people in countries without robust domestic tech industries? Does the global spread of technologies help fuel further innovation in countries with smaller tech markets, or does it reinforce the dominance of the states that are already most prominent in this sector? How can research universities maintain global collaborations and research communities in light of these national competitions, and what role does government research and development spending play in fostering innovation within its own borders and worldwide? How should intellectual property protections evolve to meet the demands of the technology industry, and how can those protections be enforced globally?

These conflicts between countries sometimes appear to challenge the feasibility of truly global technologies and networks that operate across all countries through standardized protocols and design features. Organizations like the International Organization for Standardization, the World Intellectual Property Organization, the United Nations Industrial Development Organization, and many others have tried to harmonize these policies and protocols across different countries for years, but have met with limited success when it comes to resolving the issues of greatest tension and disagreement among nations. For technology to operate in a global environment, there is a need for a much greater degree of coordination among countries and the development of common standards and norms, but governments continue to struggle to agree not just on those norms themselves but even the appropriate venue and processes for developing them. Without greater global cooperation, is it possible to maintain a global network like the internet or to promote the spread of new technologies around the world to address challenges of sustainability? What might help incentivize that cooperation moving forward, and what could new structures and process for governance of global technologies look like? Why has the tech industry’s self-regulation culture persisted? Do the same traditional drivers for public policy, such as politics of harmonization and path dependency in policy-making, still sufficiently explain policy outcomes in this space? As new technologies and their applications spread across the globe in uneven ways, how and when do they create forces of change from unexpected places?

These are some of the questions that we hope to address in the Technology and Global Change section through articles that tackle new dimensions of the global landscape of designing, developing, deploying, and assessing new technologies to address major challenges the world faces. Understanding these processes requires synthesizing knowledge from a range of different fields, including sociology, political science, economics, and history, as well as technical fields such as engineering, climate science, and computer science. A crucial part of understanding how technology has created global change and, in turn, how global changes have influenced the development of new technologies is understanding the technologies themselves in all their richness and complexity—how they work, the limits of what they can do, what they were designed to do, how they are actually used. Just as technologies themselves are becoming more complicated, so are their embeddings and relationships to the larger social, political, and legal contexts in which they exist. Scholars across all disciplines are encouraged to join us in untangling those complexities.

Josephine Wolff is an associate professor of cybersecurity policy at the Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy at Tufts University. Her book You’ll See This Message When It Is Too Late: The Legal and Economic Aftermath of Cybersecurity Breaches was published by MIT Press in 2018.

Recipient(s) will receive an email with a link to 'How Is Technology Changing the World, and How Should the World Change Technology?' and will not need an account to access the content.

Subject: How Is Technology Changing the World, and How Should the World Change Technology?

(Optional message may have a maximum of 1000 characters.)

Citing articles via

Email alerts, affiliations.

  • Special Collections
  • Review Symposia
  • Info for Authors
  • Info for Librarians
  • Editorial Team
  • Emerging Scholars Forum
  • Open Access
  • Online ISSN 2575-7350
  • Copyright © 2024 The Regents of the University of California. All Rights Reserved.

Stay Informed

Disciplines.

  • Ancient World
  • Anthropology
  • Communication
  • Criminology & Criminal Justice
  • Film & Media Studies
  • Food & Wine
  • Browse All Disciplines
  • Browse All Courses
  • Book Authors
  • Booksellers
  • Instructions
  • Journal Authors
  • Journal Editors
  • Media & Journalists
  • Planned Giving

About UC Press

  • Press Releases
  • Seasonal Catalog
  • Acquisitions Editors
  • Customer Service
  • Exam/Desk Requests
  • Media Inquiries
  • Print-Disability
  • Rights & Permissions
  • UC Press Foundation
  • © Copyright 2024 by the Regents of the University of California. All rights reserved. Privacy policy    Accessibility

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

Technological Progress and Human Perfection Essay

The longer humanity exists, the more it develops technologically; moreover, in recent years, technological progress is gaining increasing speed. This process, undoubtedly, has both positive and negative sides, and Condorcet wrote about the role of progress in human life in the 19th century. His view on technological development seems realistic and even partially predicts the current state of things. Condorcet describes progress as a constant change in various phenomena, objects, and processes, leading to an improvement in the quality of life. This can be noted in technical, cultural, educational, and other fields, which undeniably simplifies human life and helps people perform vital actions without paying attention to trifles. Unfortunately, progress can also lead to laziness and even societal degradation. In any case, one of the important goals of progress is to achieve human perfection. With it, the mind develops with incredible strength and allows people to make tremendous discoveries and perform complex actions.

However, technological progress is not always as positive as it seems. A striking example of its negative influence is the conflict between Amazon and Hachette. Even though due to technological progress people can now buy electronic books, this can negatively affect the economic condition of those who write them. Different approaches to marketing and selling books can harm writers and publishers. They may not receive enough attention and earnings and, therefore, will not be able to continue to produce new books. Nevertheless, literature is one of the necessary factors for the development of people. Thus, even despite the advantages of technological progress, humanity must always take into account its possible consequences, which will make this development a basis for social prosperity.

  • Chicago (A-D)
  • Chicago (N-B)

IvyPanda. (2022, February 18). Technological Progress and Human Perfection. https://ivypanda.com/essays/technological-progress-and-human-perfection/

"Technological Progress and Human Perfection." IvyPanda , 18 Feb. 2022, ivypanda.com/essays/technological-progress-and-human-perfection/.

IvyPanda . (2022) 'Technological Progress and Human Perfection'. 18 February.

IvyPanda . 2022. "Technological Progress and Human Perfection." February 18, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/technological-progress-and-human-perfection/.

1. IvyPanda . "Technological Progress and Human Perfection." February 18, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/technological-progress-and-human-perfection/.

Bibliography

IvyPanda . "Technological Progress and Human Perfection." February 18, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/technological-progress-and-human-perfection/.

  • Workplace Laziness in the Restaurant Business
  • Susan Glaspell’s Biography and Historical Context in Relation to Trifles
  • In-Kennel Behavior Predicts Length of Stay in Shelter Dogs
  • What Predicts Divorce: Discussion
  • Gender Role in the "Trifles" by Susan Glaspell
  • Hebrew Teachings on Diligence and Laziness: A Contrast with Wisdom and Folly
  • Gender Roles in The Yellow Wallpaper & Trifles
  • Trifles and The Story of an Hour Comparison
  • Literature Studies: Men in Susan Glaspell’s “Trifles”
  • Mystery in “Trifles” Play by Susan Glaspell
  • The Inventions of Thomas Edison
  • Electric vs. Gasoline-Powered Cars
  • Artificial Intelligence in Finland
  • Information Technology: The Impact of Paperless
  • Technology Impact on Working in Modernity
  • Dissertation
  • PowerPoint Presentation
  • Book Report/Review
  • Research Proposal
  • Math Problems
  • Proofreading
  • Movie Review
  • Cover Letter Writing
  • Personal Statement
  • Nursing Paper
  • Argumentative Essay
  • Research Paper

20 Most Prominent Technology Essay Topics And Writing Hints

Benjamin Oaks

Table of Contents

technical progress essay

So it goes without saying that the scope of technology is an endless sphere to examine. What’s more, as the topic is super wide, you can personalize your essay to make it enjoyable to work on.

Nevertheless, it may be a challenge for you to make up your mind on how and what to write about. In this case, I hope the following hints will be of great help to you!

How to choose a topic about technology for a research paper?

First of all, to write a technology essay , you need to come up with a topic that will not be too wide, yet not too narrow.

Also, remember that it will be much more entertaining and easier for you to work on the questions you actually enjoy.

If you have troubles composing the topic for your research paper, try some o the following guidelines:

  • Think of the aspects of technology you’re interested in.
  • Choose issues that are up-to-date and newsworthy .
  • Examine credible sources ; find out which questions are best covered with relevant information.
  • Write down some keywords for the remaining questions, – they will be the basis of the topic. In case you’ve got too many aspects to cover, try choosing 2-3 of them.
  • Try crafting a couple of topics . In case of emergency… find some ready-to-use ideas.
  • Look through your final ideas and pick the one you like most.
  • Do some preliminary research . Correct your topic if needed.

TOP 20 technology essay topics

Can’t come up with the idea for your perfect topic? How about choosing one from a brilliant list we’ve created for you?

  • To what extent technology has changed the way people communicate?
  • Pick up one technological invention (Internet/television/electro cars/mobile phones, etc.) and describe how it affected people’s lives.
  • History of technological progress: the first technological discoveries.
  • What would life be without modern technology?
  • Do technologies have more pros or cons? Why?
  • Is the Internet bringing people closer to each other or separating them?
  • Examine the role of technologies in your own life: to what extent you are dependent on them, can you give up using?
  • Think of the things we are losing with technological progress.
  • Choose one gadget and describe its pros and cons.
  • What technology awareness needs to be given to children nowadays?
  • Describe a new technology you consider the most prominent. Explain your choice.
  • The role of technology in globalization.
  • Technology and work: what are the advantages and disadvantages of technology in workplaces?
  • Imagine the future of technology: what life will be like in 20 years?
  • Human vs computer: who wins?
  • Reproduction technologies.
  • Health technologies that have changed the world.
  • Technology advance in genetic engineering.
  • Correlation between technological progress and human identity.
  • How has technology changed the rules of war?

Prominent topics about technology for writing

Didn’t like any of the topics above? Well, we’ve got Well, we’ve got another custom Writing list of technology topics. The following topics are more specific, but all of them are definitely thought-provoking.

  • The use of technology in education.
  • Stunning technology developed currently.
  • The most shocking modern technology inventions the majority of people still aren’t aware of.
  • Enumerate some technologies that you consider completely destructive and harmful. Explain your choice.
  • Technology and space studies.
  • The impact of technology on people’s health and values.
  • Can robots replace humans completely on the workplaces? Why?
  • Specific country and its contribution to the development of modern technology.
  • Technology and safety of transport.
  • Nanotechnologies and the scopes of their use.
  • The use of technologies in medicine.
  • Which technologies may influence people’s mental health? How?
  • Technologies that have changed our lives.
  • Do technologies have a positive or negative effect on personal safety?
  • Does modern technology help improve the educational process?

Writing about technology: the what and the why

After you’ve chosen the topic, it’s a perfect time to start working on it.

Remember… To write a successful essay or a research paper on technology, you need to organize it all well.

This means you need a plan! Here are some hints for a perfect structure:

  • Search for relevant information . You have to rely on credible sources to have up-to-date and newsworthy data. Remember that some websites may contain fakes!
  • Note some crucial aspects of your question. Later you may use them as ideas to highlight.
  • Start writing. To make it easier to cope with a lot of information you now encounter, you’d need to craft an outline . Write down a table of contents for your essay, it will be your soil to push off.
  • Start with the introduction to give the reader some understanding of the issue. Here you include some background information on the topic, historical aspect, or some definitions if needed.
  • Write the main body . Mention all your statements and support them with decent evidence. Remember that the main body should be split into paragraphs to make it readable. As a rule, one paragraph is for one idea or statement.
  • End up with a conclusion – an inference of everything said before. It has to be laconic and logical. New ideas aren’t needed here.
  • After you’ve written the paper, you may want to check it for grammar and typos . There are lots of websites and programs for this purpose. Even better, leave it for a couple of days and give it a fresh look.

The use of a technology essay example

To reassure you that writing a technology essay isn’t the end of the world, here is a free sample of the essay. It fits all the general recommendations, but you should always keep in mind that your teacher may have own vision on how the essay should be completed!

Still, it’s always great to grab some ideas!

Overall, writing an essay on technology is an incredibly valuable experience. Moreover, the topic is so wide; you most definitely will find something interesting to talk about!

Stick to the structure and don’t hesitate to discover something very specific. Technology is getting more and more stunning every day!

No time to complete your brilliant copy? We’ve got a bunch of writers, who’d be more than happy to write it for you! Any topic, tightest deadline, complete confidentiality. Hit the button to learn more.

1 Star

Sample Essay on conflict

Critique essay: your comprehensive guide to writing a+ critique essays.

technical progress essay

How to Create a Strong Conclusion Paragraph

  • Utility Menu

University Logo

  • Harvard Spain
  • Knowledge, Technology and Complexity in Economic Growth

Co-Chairs: Ricardo Hausmann (Director, Center for International Development and Professor of the Practice of Economic Development, Harvard Kennedy School of Government) and José Domínguez (Professor of Structural Engineering, School of Engineering, University of Seville). 

The application of complexity science tools to the study of society allows for the analysis of phenomena that have been hard to identify and analyze with more traditional tools, especially in the field of Economics, which in the absence of these tools has tended to work with relatively low dimensional representations of reality. But the increasing availability of more detailed information of social phenomena makes it particularly useful to use tools that can exploit this informational richness. This opens up fascinating new horizons on almost all fields of knowledge in the social sciences.

In economics, it is widely accepted that technology is the key driver of economic growth of countries, regions and cities. Technological progress allows for  the more efficient production of more and better goods and services, which is what prosperity depends on.

However, the mechanisms through which technology is developed, adopted and used in production are complex. Their more detailed analysis can allow for new findings that could have important impacts in many areas of policy, including science policy, research and development, industrial policy, and both national and regional development policies. In fact, the concept of technology itself as well as the individual and social capabilities required for its development ca now be studied at a much more fine-grained level leading to potential contributions that may impact higher education, job creation and economic growth. Clearly, there are links between education, research and development, innovation and economic activity that are part of the process we aim to uncover.

SS

The recent shift towards open innovation has resulted in increased flows of knowledge and new types of cooperation between education institutions, research organizations and business. Top corporate R&D investors worldwide lead the development of many emerging technologies. This is evident from an examination of the technology fields in which these companies intensified their inventive activities in the recent years and the contribution of top R&D investors to the overall development of these fields. Top corporate R&D investors accelerated their inventive activities in areas such as engines, automated driving systems, big data, artificial intelligence, 3-D printing and information and communication technologies.

It is necessary to remember that the two main ingredients for the development of new technology are codified knowledge in the form of theories, frameworks, scientific papers, patents, recipes, protocols, routines and instruction manuals and tacit knowledge or knowhow, which is acquired through learning by doing in a long process of imitation and repetition and which exists only in brains . The development of science, technology, innovation and production require both codified and tacit knowledge but the codifiable component of science and technology get registered, respectively, in the form of scientific publications and patents, and these are grouped into categories. Scientific publications, patents, industries, occupations and products are proxies of scientific knowledge, technological development, economic activity and human skills.

They form what is known as a multiplex network with six kinds of nodes where geographic location represents the last one. Understanding relations within each layer, e.g., the knowledge space, the patent space, the industry space, the occupation space, the product space and the country (or location space); and across layers should shed light on the foundations of countries economic development and the policies to be implemented in all of these areas to promote it.

Policies towards science, technology and innovation (STI) would benefit enormously from a deeper and more detailed understanding of the 6-fold multiplex that this research wants to uncover. What are the detailed connections between areas of science, as captured by journal publications and patents. What forms of human collaboration are necessary for the authorship of papers and patents? And for national and local authorities: What are the connections between a local effort in science and local innovation? What are the backward linkages of industrial diversification on the local capacity to create patents and scientific papers? Which occupations are key to facilitate the diffusion of industries to particular locations and what are the educational profiles of those occupations? What is the role of human mobility and the attraction of talent in the successful development of STI?

To sum up, this study group pursues three purposes:

  • To analyze empirically the nature of the partnerships and ecosystem relations that underpin scientific and technological progress and its manifestation in the development of new industries, the appearance of new products and the formation of new teams of people with different and complementary occupations. To do this, we will carry out a research agenda to uncover these connections.  
  • To develop tools in order to assess the position of each country and region in the multiplex and its evolution over time in order to evaluate their “adjacent possible” in a way that can help them plan their efforts towards progress.  
  • To expand the dimensions that the quantitative tools of CID’s Atlas of Economic Complexity can offer its worldwide users, thus allowing policymakers, corporations, STI participants and the broader public to benefit from the results of the research.
  • Southern Europe in the EU
  • European Union Law & Government
  • Future Challenges in Federated Cloud Computing
  • Internationalization and Innovation in Higher Education (I2HE)
  • Latin American Integration in the Globalization Era
  • Studies on Life and Human Dignity
  • Arts and Technologies in Leadership (ATL): The global pre-texts project
  • Big Data and Machine Learning: Shaping the Future of Healthcare
  • Commons-based peer production (CBPP)
  • Communication and Health
  • Data-centric Cloud Computing
  • Botanical Collections and Herbaria: New Insights and Challenges
  • Data Science
  • Functional Foods, Bioactives and Human Health
  • Global Governance
  • Pollutants and toxic compounds in food and environment: zebrafish as a model for studying toxicological effects
  • Teaching and Learning Science in Outdoor Environments (TeLeSOE).
  • Urban Innovation
  • Inquiries in Ethics in Communication and Organizations (IECO)
  • Studying and improving Mathematics instruction in secondary schools in Spain (SiMiS)
  • Sustainable Cities
  • The Santiago Cathedral
  • Transatlantic Literatures
  • Initiatives
  • International Campuses of Excellence
  • Jean Monnet ad Personam Chair in EU Law and Government
  • Erasmus + Jean Monnet Project

Fellowship Opportunity

RAMÓN ARECES FOUNDATION FELLOWSHIP AT HARVARD CENTER FOR EUROPEAN STUDIES (CES)

The Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies (CES) is pleased to announce the creation of the  Ramón Areces Fellowship . This new fellowship is made possible through a generous gift by the  Ramón Areces Foundation   to enable outstanding post-doctoral, early-career stage Spanish scholars to undertake research in-residence at CES for one academic year starting in September 2023. The Ramón Areces Fellowship is made possible through a generous gift by the  Ramón Areces Foundation . The Madrid-based foundation was established in 1976 to provide research and learning opportunities for Spanish citizens and to support initiatives that advance solutions to societal challenges in the realms of science, education, culture and economics.

ces

technical progress essay

  • Previous Article
  • 1 0000000404811396 https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Advances in artificial intelligence and automation have the potential to be labor-saving and to increase inequality and poverty around the globe. They also give rise to winner-takes-all dynamics that advantage highly skilled individuals and countries that are at the forefront of technological progress. We analyze the economic forces behind these developments and delineate domestic economic policies to mitigate the adverse effects while leveraging the potential gains from technological advances. We also propose reforms to the global system of governance that make the benefits of advances in artificial intelligence more inclusive.

  • I. Introduction

Advances in artificial intelligence (AI) and related forms of automation technologies have led to growing fears about job losses and increasing inequality. This concern is widespread in high-income countries. Developing countries and emerging market economies should be even more concerned than high-income countries, as their comparative advantage in the world economy relies on abundant labor and natural resources. Declining returns to labor and natural resources as well as the winner-takes-all dynamics brought on by new information technologies could lead to further immiseration in the developing world. This could undermine the rapid gains that have been the hallmark of success in development over the past fifty years and threaten the progress made in reducing poverty and inequality.

For many decades, there was a presumption that advances in technology would benefit all— embodied by the trickle-down dogma that characterized neoliberalism. And for some time, this presumption was in fact justified. For example, for the three decades following World War II, the US economy and many other high-income and developing countries experienced broadly shared increases in living standards. However, over the past half-century, output growth and median worker incomes started to decouple.

Moreover, economic theory cautions that technological progress is likely to create both winners and losers (see Korinek and Stiglitz, 2019 , for a review). As long as the winners and losers from technological progress are located within the same country, there is at least the possibility that domestic policy measures can compensate the losers. However, when technological progress deteriorates the terms of trade and thus undermines the comparative advantage of entire countries, then entire nations may be worse off except if the winners within one country compensate the losers in other countries, which seems politically very difficult.

This paper argues that concerns about whether technological progress leads to inclusive growth are indeed justified – and that especially developing countries may face a stark new set of challenges going forward. However, we propose policies that can mitigate the adverse effects so that advances in technology lead to a world with greater shared prosperity. This will require new domestic polices and development strategies as well as strong international cooperation and a rewriting of the global rules governing the information economy.

We start by laying out the key properties of AI and related automation technologies that underlie the concerns about recent technological progress. 2 AI is likely to be labor-saving and resource-saving, devaluing the sources of comparative advantage of many developing countries and deteriorating their terms of trade. Being an information technology, AI also tends to give rise to natural monopolies, creating a small set of so-called superstar firms that are located in a few powerful countries but serve the entire world economy. Moreover, under reasonable assumptions, the rate and direction of technological progress chosen by the market are generally suboptimal ( Korinek and Stiglitz, 2019 ). This creates the possibility of steering innovation in AI and other technologies in directions that are more beneficial to humanity at large, for example, preserving the planet or creating satisfying employment opportunities, rather than substituting for labor and creating more unemployment and inequality.

Taking a step back, we evaluate to what extent the discussed concerns about technological progress are justified, given what we know at present. There is vast uncertainty about the impact of AI, even among experts in the field. Some argue that AI is less important than the big innovations of the 20 th century and will have rather limited impact on the economy, whereas others go as far as predicting that AI will lead to more rapid technological progress than mankind has ever seen before.

In this context, we discuss how to reconcile the buzz among technologists over the past decade with economic data that suggests rather modest productivity increases over the period – encapsulated by the so-called productivity puzzle. We also analyze how the forces generated by progress in AI interact with other recent developments, in particular with the recovery from COVID-19, with secular population dynamics, and with the need for a Green Transition.

Despite the uncertainties surrounding AI, its potentially dramatic consequences suggest that we should steer our own research in directions where the expected social value added of economic analysis is greatest: we need to think particularly hard about potential events that would be highly disruptive to our society.

To grasp the historical nature of what is going on, we look at the broader history of technological progress. Humanity spent much of its history at a Malthusian stage in which the vast majority of the population lived at subsistence levels. The Industrial Revolution that lifted living standards started a bit over two centuries ago, making it a mere blip in the history of human civilization. For developing countries, the era of manufacturing-based export-led growth that enabled the East Asian Miracle stretched over the past half-century – only one quarter of the history of the Industrial Revolution. It is conceivable that we are now going into another era. There is even a risk that the terms-of-trade losses generated by progress in AI may erase much of the gains that the developing countries have made in recent decades.

However, the Industrial Revolution also offers ample lessons on how to manage innovation in a positive way: technological revolutions are very disruptive, but collective action can mitigate the adverse effects and generate an environment in which the gains are shared broadly. The labor-using nature of the Industrial Revolution ushered in an Age of Labor in which the economic gains of workers also shifted political dynamics in their favor, but there is a risk that future labor-saving progress may do the opposite. The decline of manufacturing will require a new development model that follows a more multi-pronged strategy to replace the manufacturing-based export-led growth model.

The key policy question is how countries can improve the likelihood of benign outcomes from technological progress. This is especially pertinent for developing countries, but it is also a challenge for advanced economies to develop policies that ensure that technological advances lead to broadly shared prosperity and that their adverse effects are mitigated. We delineate here a number of such policies. Taxation and redistribution are a first line of defense to compensate the losers of progress, although the scope for redistribution may be limited in developing countries.

Targeted expenditure policies can serve double duty by providing both income to workers and a valuable social return – for example, investments in education or infrastructure are labor intensive and enhance human capital and the physical infrastructure of countries, both of which are important in bridging the digital divide and ensuring that all citizens can participate in the opportunities afforded by digital technologies.

To replace the manufacturing-based export-led growth model, developing countries will need to steer technological progress and technology adoption in new directions, in part by leveraging the opportunities that AI and other digital technologies afford in agriculture and services.

Finally, we describe a set of policies at the supra-national level to reform our global system of governance in a way that developing countries can benefit from advances in AI and other information technologies while addressing the downsides of these new technologies. We need to design a global tax regime for the digital age that enables countries to raise taxes on transactions that occur within their borders. Competition policy is also increasingly a question that transcends national borders as the footprint of the digital giants is global and authorities in their countries of origin do not face the correct incentives to ensure a competitive marketplace. Intellectual property regimes need to be adapted so they are attuned to the needs and circumstances of developing countries. Moreover, information policy including the regulation of data needs to be discussed at the supra-national level to provide a voice to developing countries that could otherwise not influence the design of such policies.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In the second section, we provide an overview of the downside risks of technological progress, with special emphasis on potential AI-induced economic disruptions; in the third, we discuss the uncertainties surrounding the nature and level of the impacts as well as the broader context. The fourth section reviews what we can learn from the bigger historical picture of technological progress. The fifth section distills the critical role of government policy in managing the effects of technological progress and enabling the benefits of innovation to be widely shared. The sixth section analyzes how our global system of governance needs to be updated to allow developing countries to maximize the benefits and minimize the costs of advances in AI and related technologies.

II. Downside Risks of Technological Progress

Many technology optimists suggest that productivity gains go hand in hand with real wage gains. This presumption that technological progress would benefit all was also embodied by the trickle-down dogma that has characterized neoliberalism. However, the presumption was supported neither by theory nor evidence; indeed, economic theory has always held that advances in technology do not necessarily benefit all and may create winners and losers. The data ( Figure 1 ) show that in recent decades, many countries have experienced episodes during which wages lagged productivity growth. Moreover, as we argue below, even where average wages did keep up with productivity, median wages may not have, and there is a risk that any positive gains seen in the past may not continue.

Figure 1.

Productivity and Earnings Growth

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2021, 166; 10.5089/9781513583280.001.A001

  • Download Figure
  • Download figure as PowerPoint slide

Figure 2 illustrates that the income gains associated with technological progress have been highly unevenly distributed. In the US and other high-income countries, most of the benefits of growth have gone to those at the top, resulting in widening income inequality in most advanced economies since the early 1980s, reversing an earlier downward trend in many countries.

Figure 2.

Income Inequality over Time, 1960–2015

How can we reconcile this with economic theory? In the context of a competitive economy, we can think of technological progress as moving out the production possibility frontier: one can get more of any output for a given amount of inputs. But this increase in production possibilities does not tell us how the gains from progress will be distributed. In our simplest economic models, for example, if we assume a competitive economy with a Cobb-Douglas production function, relative shares are fixed.

However, in the more general case, technical change may change the distribution of income, so that, for instance, labor gets a smaller share of a larger pie. If its share decreases enough, workers could even be worse off. Whether wages increase or decrease depends on what happens to the demand for labor at existing wages. Using the terminology first introduced by Hicks, technical change that leads to a decrease in the relative share of labor is called capital-biased; if it leads to a decrease in the share of unskilled labor, it is called skill-biased; if it leads to an outright reduction in wages, it is called labor-saving. The US, for example, has experienced routine-biased technological change that has replaced workers engaged in both manual and cognitive routine activities since the 1980s and that has contributed to the hollowing out of the middle class ( Autor et al., 2003 ).

Korinek and Stiglitz (2019) show that the distributive effects of innovations can be seen as generating quasi-rents -aside from delivering direct gains to innovators, innovations lead to changes in factor demands, for example lowering demand for unskilled labor and raising demand for skilled labor, and the affected workers experience gains or losses. The winners of progress (e.g. the skilled workers in our example) experience these gains without having contributed to the innovation, obtaining quasi-rents, whereas the losers experience losses without any fault of their own. That, in turn, has an important implication: governments can capture some of the quasi-rents by taxing the winners and redistributing it; and given the nature of the gains, governments may even be able to raise taxes in ways that have no or limited distortionary effects, for example if the winners include owners of fixed factors such as land. Thus, “managed” technological progress could allow for Pareto-improving outcomes.

However, there is a big difference between looking at the impacts of AI within a single country and from a global perspective. When the benefits are experienced in one country and the cost is borne in another, a Pareto improvement would require that the winners compensate the losers across national boundaries. Today, such cross-border transfers are voluntary and limited.

As a result, the fruits of technological progress will be unequally shared; but more troublesome is that while some countries may gain a great deal, others will lose. These differences will be reflected, respectively, in improvements and deteriorations of countries’ terms of trade. In the following, we will analyze several of the specific forms of progress that the AI revolution and related automation technologies are likely to induce, with particular focus on how they may hurt developing countries.

  • A. Labor-Saving Technological Progress

Many observers are concerned that AI may be labor-saving, that is, cause a decline in the demand for labor at existing factor prices. If this occurs, equilibrium wages will decrease and workers will be worse off.

As we have noted, over the past half-century, the US and many other countries seem to have experienced technological progress that was biased against workers with lower levels of education performing routine tasks, sufficiently biased that it may even have been labor-saving in that segment, reducing such workers’ real incomes. For example, Autor et al. (2003) observe that from the 1970s to the 1990s, while computerization was a substitute for an increasing number of routine tasks, technological change increased the productivity of workers in non-routine jobs that involved problem-solving and complex communications tasks. These changes in technology may have explained nearly 2/3 of the relative demand shift toward college-educated labor over that period. Similarly, more recently, Acemoglu and Restrepo (2020) estimated significant adverse employment and wage effects from the introduction of industrial robots in the US, concentrated in manufacturing and among routine manual, blue-collar, assembly, and related occupations, helping to explain the dramatic increase in wage dispersion across skill groups over the past five decades ( Figure 3 ).

Figure 3.

Rising Wage-Skill Premia in the US

(Real Wages of Full Time U.S. Male Workers, 1963 = 100)

This job polarization in terms of wages has also been reflected in relative employment dynamics. Employment in nonroutine jobs has continued to grow steadily in the US, while that in routine jobs has stagnated, or in some periods declined, since around 1990, contributing, as we have noted, to a “hollowing out of the middle” ( Figure 4 ). 3 OECD (2019) note that middle-skilled jobs may be the most prone to both automation and offshoring, as they most encompass routine tasks that are relatively easy to automate (or offshore). 4

Figure 4.

Employment in Routine vs. Non-Routine Jobs

(Persons, millions)

Standard models of aggregate production functions with skilled and unskilled labor-augmenting progress and capital-augmenting progress can generate the observed patterns of movements in factor prices and shares, depending on patterns of progress as well as elasticities and cross-elasticities of substitution. Acemoglu and Restrepo (2019a) formulate a particular model in which the displacement of workers by robots will reduce the labor share of income and may be labor-saving if the productivity gains from the robots are modest. Berg et al. (2018) focus on the differential effects of technological progress across worker groups and shows that technological progress may be unskilled-labor-saving because that type of labor is easily substituted for by robots; by contrast, high-skilled labor is likely complementary to robots and will benefit from technological progress; as a result, technological advances risk bringing about large increases in inequality. Automation may also worsen inequality along other dimensions—for example, in sectors where women occupy more routine jobs ( Brussevich et al., 2018 ).

Even if technological progress is labor-saving in the short run, it may also trigger additional accumulation of capital that is complementary to labor, benefiting labor in the long run. For example, Stiglitz (2015) and Caselli and Manning (2019) show that in an economy with capital and labor only, in which long-run capital accumulation is determined by an exogenous interest rate, labor will always gain. 5 Ultimately, however, impacts on inequality depend on whether there are other scarce limiting factors in the economy, for example, natural resources or land, which would benefit from technological progress and ultimately become more scarce as the factors “capital” and “machine-replacing labor” become more abundant and cheaper. Indeed, Korinek and Stiglitz (2021a) show that if this is the case, then, without government intervention, labor may lose out from technological progress even in the long run.

At a global level, similar dynamics may play out. Although labor-saving technological progress would make the world as a whole richer, it would hit developing countries that have a comparative advantage in cheap labor particularly hard. If worldwide demand for labor, or for unskilled labor, declines, such countries would experience a significant deterioration in their terms of trade and lose a substantial fraction of their export income. Labor-saving progress may not only create winners and losers within the affected developing countries, but it may make entire countries on net worse off. Alonso et al. (2020) find that improvements in the productivity of “robots” could drive divergence, as advanced countries benefit from computerization more given their higher initial capital stock.

However, it is also conceivable that other forms of advances in technology could benefit workers: intelligence-assisting devices and algorithms (IA) may be complementary to labor rather than substituting for it, thus enhancing the prospects of labor. Innovations that fall into this category may include augmented reality (AR), machine learning (ML) algorithms that help analyze complex data, and other forms of integration of AI with humans. 6 Automation technologies frequently affect particular tasks but not (entire) jobs, which consist of multiple tasks (see, e.g., Acemoglu and Autor, 2011 )—IA innovations may help workers be more productive in their jobs by taking over, or improving, certain tasks. For example, a doctor is engaged in diagnosis but also in explaining the diagnosis to the patient. AI may do a better job in diagnosis – for example, in radiology – but it may not quite replace the doctor in communicating with the patient, at least not yet.

Driverless trucks provide another example: truck driving provides significant employment opportunities for men with only a high school education so there is understandably concern for the disruption that self-driving trucks might bring about. But truck drivers also perform a number of related tasks – they fill orders, load and unload, monitor the truck, and more – not all of which may be easily automated. More generally, most jobs have multiple dimensions and consist of multiple tasks. With some tasks automated, workers will be able to devote more attention to, and perform better at, those tasks that are not. Importantly, both AI and IA imply extensive restructuring of the economy.

The central concern of this paper remains: there may be a reduction in the demand for labor, especially for unskilled labor. We will further evaluate whether or not these fears are justified below in Section 3. If, however, it turns out that AI is labor saving, and especially if it is unskilled labor saving, the consequences for developing countries would be severe. This is the “resource” which constitutes their comparative advantage and in which they are relatively rich. The convergence in standards of living between developing countries and developed that has marked the past half century would be arrested, even reversed. It would also present great challenges to domestic policy within developing countries. In many parts of the world, inequalities within developing countries are greater than in developed. AI would exacerbate those inequalities – and developing countries often lack the institutional capacities to counteract them.

  • B. Resource-Saving Technological Progress

Another type of progress that is of great concern to some developing countries is resource-saving technological progress. This has gotten less attention than labor-saving progress so far (e.g., Solow, 2009 ), but AI and other digital technologies have often been praised for their potential to produce more output with fewer natural resources. For instance, they may help reduce the demand for depletable natural resources and lower carbon emissions. Examples include algorithms that optimize efficiency in data centers or that make transportation networks more efficient. Technologies that enable telework may also reduce the carbon footprint of workers. 7 Thus, such resource-saving innovations may have adverse distributional effects on developing countries that have a comparative advantage in natural resources, and that have specialized in exporting them. The impact on exporters of different types of natural resources may be quite different – for example, exporters of carbon-based energy will fare differently from exporters of rare earth metals.

Consider oil-exporting countries, which have already experienced many developmental challenges while being resource-rich. Resource-saving AI, while saving the planet, would make them resource-poor countries that still experience the same developmental challenges. The challenges of addressing global inequality under such a scenario would be an order of magnitude larger than they are even today, posing a test for the global community. A number of oil-exporting countries rely on their export revenue to buy food and other basic essentials—if they lose their ability to export oil, the consequences would be dire. Thus, as in the case of labor-saving technological progress, the world as a whole may be better off—in this case by undoing resource scarcity and reducing climate change—but not all countries would benefit. 8

  • C. Information, Digital Monopolies and Superstars

So far we have considered the effects of technological change in a competitive environment. However, the rise of AI and other information technologies may also lead to greater concentrations of market power. As a result, the economy may move to an equilibrium that is less competitive and more distorted by market power, with greater rents for dominant firms. Actors with market power will use that power to advantage themselves. The resulting distortions may offset part of the benefits of innovation, exacerbating the adverse distributive effects of labor-saving or resource-saving innovation. With any inequality-averse social welfare function, societal welfare could decrease.

While the assumption of competitive markets often provides a useful benchmark, that model becomes less appropriate as one considers an economy that is dominated by AI. It is hard to conceive of an AI economy being competitive, or at least well-described by the standard competitive equilibrium model.

There are several reasons why advances in AI may intensify market power. First, AI is an information good, and information goods are different from other goods in that they are non-rivalrous – they can be used at close-to-zero marginal cost, implying that a single firm can serve a very large market. Moreover, the creation of AI codes or ML algorithms typically involves high sunk costs and/or fixed costs – in a private market, firms need to earn monopoly rents to recoup these costs. Moreover, even small sunk costs may result in markets not being contestable, i.e., there could be sustained rents and profits. In addition, AI applications and platforms typically involve significant network externalities. Some of these arise because firms accumulate vast amounts of data that allow them to train their algorithms better than those of the competition. All of these effects create large barriers to entry and a tendency towards creating large monopolies, sometimes also called “superstar” effects (see, e.g., Korinek and Ng, 2019 , and Stiglitz and Greenwald, 2014a ).

Some authors have identified a growing number of “superstar firms” in the economy that are “super profitable” (see, e.g., Autor et al., 2020 ). However, rather than reflecting “super-productive” technology, much of these profits may arise from the exercise of monopoly power that is derived from the nature of these information technologies. For example, in the US, a large fraction of the gains in the stock market over the past decade have been concentrated in digital giants, to an important extent driven by their market power. Moreover, algorithmic advances have also enabled digital firms to extract more consumer surplus through discriminatory pricing.

Such superstar and monopoly effects are likely to play out not only at a company level but also at a country level, and they are likely to be particularly severe in the context of AI. They may be exacerbated by agglomeration economies associated with R&D in AI. There is a risk that those countries that lead in the advancement in AI may reap all the benefits, becoming “superstar countries” and reaping all the rents associated with the development of AI. The rest of the world, and in particular most developing and emerging economies, may be left behind, with the notable exception of China – one of the leaders in AI. Moreover, to the extent that firms or countries can protect their knowledge, the resulting monopolization of knowledge may also impede the catching-up process. Importantly, even if competitors could “steal” a superstar’s knowledge, this may not necessarily be sufficient as the superstars can continuously improve their algorithms based on their users’ data, thus remaining, perhaps permanently, ahead. In the past, advances in technology were driven to an important extent by basic research that was financed by governments in high-income countries and that was freely available to all—including to developing countries. This too may change with AI.

Some observers suggest as a silver lining for developing countries in that ML technologies are reliant on data and that more diverse data contain more information. Thus, selling data might generate some income for developing countries. However, this is unlikely to make up for their lost income as the marginal return to more diverse data may be limited. Moreover, future advances in ML algorithms may make them less reliant on large quantities of data and instead require more specific, tailored data.

  • D. Misguided Technological Progress

Economic theory has illuminated why the nature of innovation (e.g., the factor bias) may not be welfare maximizing. Much of economics takes the factor bias of technological change as exogenously given, and the standard economic welfare theorems assert the efficiency of competitive market economies for a given level of technology. However, the direction and rate of technological progress are themselves economic decisions, as emphasized by the literature on induced innovation (e.g. Kennedy, 1964 ; von Weizsäcker, 1966 ; Samuelson, 1965 ; Atkinson and Stiglitz, 1969 ; Acemoglu, 1998 , 2002 ; Stiglitz, 2006 ). There is no analogue of the welfare theorems for innovation: markets on their own will not in general be efficient either in the level or direction (nature) of innovative activity and technological change. The market may even provide incentives for innovations that reduce efficiency by absorbing more resources than they create for society, as may be the case, for example, for high-frequency trading. This calls for policy to actively steer technological progress, as we will discuss further below.

The fundamental problem is that knowledge is a public good, in the Samuelsonian sense. If it is to be privately financed and produced, there must be inefficient restraints on the use of knowledge, and those restraints typically also give rise to market power. If there are no restraints on the use of knowledge, then innovators cannot appropriate the returns to their production of knowledge, and so they will have little incentive to innovate. 9 When knowledge is produced as a by-product of learning or investing, the inability to fully appropriate all the learning benefits will lead to under production or underinvestment in sectors of the economy associated with high learning and learning spillovers. As Greenwald and Stiglitz (2006) and Stiglitz and Greenwald (2014a) point out, this has important implications for developmental policy, providing a rationale for industrial and trade policies. 10

More recent literature has drawn attention not only to biases in the level and pace of innovation but also to the direction. In economies with incomplete risk markets and imperfect and/or asymmetric information (i.e., in all real-world economies), the equilibrium is not constrained Pareto efficient, and prices do not necessarily give the “correct” signal to innovators on the direction of innovation. There are pecuniary externalities that matter. 11 For instance, in the Shapiro-Stiglitz (1984) efficiency wage model, where unemployment acts as a disciplining device to discourage shirking in the context of a labor market with imperfect and costly monitoring, there will be too much labor-augmenting technological progress, resulting in too high a level of unemployment ( Stiglitz, 2006 ). There are multiple other biases, for example, towards innovative activities in which intellectual property rights are more easily secured, and in drugs, to me-too innovations, where private returns can markedly exceed social returns.

Markets do not care about income distribution. Market forces may drive economic decisions towards efficiency—in the narrow, microeconomic sense— but will not give any consideration to the distributive consequences. Recent contributions, however, have emphasized that overall economic performance can be affected by inequality ( Ostry et al., 2019 ; Stiglitz, 2013 ); obviously, individual entrepreneurs will not take into account this macroeconomic externality, and accordingly the market will be biased towards producing too much labor-saving innovation, creating a role for redistributive policies. In addition, Korinek and Stiglitz (2020) show that in the presence of constraints on redistribution, policy can improve welfare by steering innovation to take into account its distributive implications.

There are some self-correcting forces: for example, if labor is getting cheaper, innovators face smaller incentives to save on labor, providing a corrective mechanism within the market economy to an ever-decreasing share of labor, but this mechanism no longer works when wages are set by efficiency wage considerations or reach subsistence levels. 12

What is most relevant for developing countries is that these distributive implications extend across borders, and so decisions made in one country have effects on other countries that the innovating country and the innovators within that country have no incentive to consider. Even if markets were efficient in the choice of technology for the conditions of the country in which the innovation occurs, those conditions are markedly different from the conditions in other countries. In developing countries, a key question is about adopting appropriate technologies rather than innovating, but the same kind of analysis that argues for the need for government intervention in steering technological innovation also provides arguments for intervention in steering technology adoption. This is especially so if, after the initial adoption of technology from abroad, there is further adaptation to local circumstances, and the benefits and costs of the technological evolution are not fully appropriated, for example, in the process of learning by doing. These concerns have long been at the center of concern of industrial policy.

  • E. Broader Harms Associated with AI

There are also a number of broader harms associated with AI that have recently received a lot of attention—the ways in which new technology can affect security (including cybersecurity), privacy, incitement to “bad” behavior, including through hate speech, political manipulation, and, in the economic arena, price discrimination, sometimes exacerbating pre-existing societal divides.

While these matters affect both high-income and developing economies, an important concern is that the international community may address them in a way that does not reflect the priorities and needs of developing countries. Policymakers in many countries are beginning to discuss appropriate regulatory regimes and a set of rules to address these potential harms. It is unclear whether developing countries and emerging markets will be sufficiently represented at the table when these discussions take place. In fact, many of the standards, rules and regulations are likely to be set by high-income countries and China (e.g., Ding et al., 2018 ; Sacks, 2018 ), even though the impacts may be larger, and potentially different, on developing countries and emerging markets.

Moreover, the institutional capacity of developing countries to counter these harms may be more limited—especially when facing off against the technology giants. Weaker institutional foundations may make some countries more prone to abuses of autocratic and totalitarian leaders using mis-/disinformation and surveillance technologies. Less educated populations may suffer more from the consequences of mis-/disinformation, such as those associated with the anti-vaccine movement.

III. Evaluating the Uncertainties and Opportunities

  • A. Uncertainty about the Pace and Scale of Progress

The impact of technological change depends heavily on its pace and scale. If it occurs slowly, there is time to adjust. If automation is limited to a few tasks or sectors at a time, the impacts will be limited. However, there is a great degree of uncertainty about the pace of change and the magnitude of the coming disruption, even among experts in this area. Some economists (e.g., Gordon, 2016 ) assert that we are not in an era of unprecedented innovation, and that economic growth will be less rapid in the future than it has been over the past century. In fact, Gordon (2016) argues that indoor toilets and electricity had far bigger consequences on people’s standards of living than more recent innovations. Another view is that AI is a truly transformative technology—a General-Purpose Technology (GPT)—that has the potential to revolutionize every sector of the economy (e.g., Trajtenberg, 2019 ). Like steam engines or electricity in previous technological revolutions, this view predicts that AI will lead to significant productivity gains and structural changes across the entire economy.

An even more radical perspective that goes back to John von Neumann is that AI may eventually advance to a point where AI systems reach human levels of general intelligence. This may imply that they can also do research, design better versions of themselves and thereby recursively self-improve, giving rise to accelerating technological progress and, in the words of von Neumann, “the appearance of approaching some essential singularity in the history of the race beyond which human affairs, as we know them, could not continue” (see Ulam, 1958 ). 13 The concept of such a singularity has been popularized by Good (1965) , Vinge (1993) and Kurzweil (2005) , and is being increasingly discussed among economists (e.g. Nordhaus, 2015 ; Aghion et al., 2017 ). Predictions of when such a chain of events might occur, however, continue to be perpetually revised— Armstrong et al. (2014) note that over the past six decades or so analysts have continued to expect “the development of [general] AI [to occur] within 15–25 years from whenever the prediction is made.” 14

This last perspective emphasizes that AI-driven machines may not only be physically stronger than humans and better and faster at processing information, but in an increasing number of domains, they may also learn better and faster than humans. 15 Thus, AI may be much more disruptive than a “mere” GPT; AI programs are increasingly replacing tasks previously performed by humans. If machines can engage in all tasks that have traditionally been performed by labor, and if they can do so at ever lower cost, then traditional labor would eventually become redundant, with the marginal product of human labor possibly falling so low that it no longer covers the subsistence cost necessary to keep a human alive ( Korinek and Stiglitz, 2019 ). This would represent the extreme case of labor-saving innovation: it is in fact labor-replacing innovation – employing labor would become a strictly dominated technology. 16

We discussed earlier some studies examining which jobs may be replaced by automation and AI in coming decades, typically based on job- or task-level data. The predictions in these studies vary widely, ranging from a relatively small percentage of 14% of all jobs ( OECD, 2019 ) to an estimate of 20–25% (Bain and Company, 2018) and almost 50% by Frey and Osborne (2017) and McKinsey Global Institute (2017) . Even the lower numbers suggest a significant effect, especially because the impact may be concentrated in certain industries and among certain groups of workers, specifically among unskilled and routine jobs. Knowing what fraction of all jobs will be lost to AI therefore does not necessarily provide a good metric of the impact on income distribution, and especially so in the short run.

Applying our earlier insights on steering innovation to economic research, economists should steer their research in directions where the expected social value added of economic analysis is greatest, that is, where it has the highest welfare impact.

Even if some of the described scenarios have a relatively low probability, it is important to think particularly hard about events that will be highly disruptive to society, to think through the consequences, and to prepare for how we might ameliorate some of the more adverse effects. Extensive labor replacing innovation would be such an event. Even if one places a relatively low probability on such an event—and one may argue that it is not actually a low-probability event—the associated social repercussions would be sufficiently large that it makes sense to focus attention on such an event. Studying scenarios that pose the most adverse social impacts would better prepare economies to deal with them when they occur— and they also provide valuable lessons for scenarios in which the impact is less stark.

  • B. The Productivity Puzzle: Are We Really in an Era of Unprecedented Innovation?

In relating the debate about the economic significance of AI-based innovation to recent economic data, we encounter a well-known puzzle: if we are really living in an era of significant technological disruption, why are the increases in innovation not showing up in GDP data? This is analogous to the puzzle of missing productivity growth from computerization that Bob Solow described in the 1980s when the GPT of the time – computers – spread throughout the economy ( Solow, 1987 ). It took until the following decade for US national accounts to show a pickup in productivity growth. Part of the explanation for the productivity puzzle is that there are long lags, as was the case for computerization. At present, AI is influential in a limited number of sectors, like inventing better ways of advertising. Even if AI is transforming advertising, this will not transform our overall standard of living. (In this particular case, it may actually lower overall efficiency, as it may undermine the price system by enabling pervasive discriminatory pricing.) Going forward, many sectors of the economy will require complementary investments and changes in processes and organization as well as new skills among their workers to take full advantage of AI (see e.g. Brynjolfsson et al., 2019 ).

Another part of the explanation of the productivity puzzle is that there are difficult measurement problems. Many recent technologies may have led to increases in societal welfare that are not captured by GDP (see e.g. Brynjolfsson, 2020 ). For example, when online services are exchanged against “eyeballs,” i.e., when users are exposed to advertisements instead of paying for services, the benefits to consumers are not included. 17

C. Putting AI in the Broader Context of Development

There are several other important factors that are relevant when it comes to managing the potential adverse effects of AI on developing countries in coming decades.

The COVID-19 pandemic has imposed an extra shadow cost on physical interaction with humans, which is likely to accelerate the automation of jobs that require physical interaction (see e.g. Korinek and Stiglitz, 2021b ). The resulting changes will have long-lasting effects on the economy, even after the pandemic is overcome. The new technologies that are introduced now will reduce the demand for labor worldwide for some time to come. 18

  • Population Dynamics

Population dynamics will interact in important ways with labor-saving or -replacing technologies (see e.g. Varian, 2020 ). In countries with rapidly growing working-age populations, such as in many African countries, lots of new jobs will have to be created to maintain a given employment rate. Advances in automation that are developed in high-income countries and easily deployed around the world will make this more difficult. However, the large supply of labor may slow down the development and adoption of automation technologies within such countries (although the evidence in several countries suggests that at least in large export-oriented manufacturing, the technologies employed are remarkably similar to those in advanced countries; see Rodrik, 2011 ). 19 Moreover, young populations also generate significant demand for education, which in turn creates jobs. Overall, even countries like India face difficulties in creating enough formal sector jobs to keep pace with the growing working age population. The faster growth of population makes capital deepening more difficult, slowing the pace of growth in income per capita.

Conversely, in countries in which the working-age population is declining, such as China, the impact of job automation on the workforce is mitigated as workers that are replaced by technological progress can simply retire. Moreover, aging populations create large service sector needs, particularly in healthcare. Many of these service sector jobs are unlikely to be replaced by automation or AI in the near future. Overall, the evidence suggests that aging societies adopt new technologies and automate ( Acemoglu and Restrepo, 2019b and Figure 5 ). 20

Figure 5.

Population Aging and Automation

  • The Green Transition

A third important force affecting developing countries in coming decades is the threat of global warming, which calls for significant public policy interventions to facilitate the Green Transition, i.e., the transition away from an economy that is dependent on fossil fuels to one that is more environmentally sustainable and relies more on renewable energy. Without global policies to save our planet, developing countries will experience some of the largest losses from global warming.

There are many similarities between the effects of AI and the Green Transition. Both involve large changes in relative prices and generate significant redistributions, and many developing countries will be strongly affected. The Green Transition is similar to resource-saving innovation and risks undermining the standard of living of oil-exporting countries, among which there are a number of low-income countries.

There is also an important complementarity between the Green Transition and AI: the Green Transition is likely to increase the demand for labor which could offset some of the negative effects on labor demand of automation and AI. Indeed, given the labor needed for the Green Transition, the labor replacement due to automation and AI in many activities, including manufacturing, could be considered a fortunate development enabling countries to better address the challenges of climate change. There is thus an inherent tension in frequent claims that on the one hand economies cannot afford to mitigate climate change (i.e., that there are insufficient resources), and on the other hand concerns over a potential crisis with a surplus of labor arising from labor-saving AI. 21, 22

However, we do face challenges in how to channel surplus resources into what is required for the Green Transition. Some of the skill sets of those labor resources freed up by technological progress will differ from those needed in the Green Transition, although Louie and Pearce (2016) argue that the retraining costs would be moderate , and many of the investments (such as installing solar panels) require only limited skills.

There may be institutional constraints that make it difficult to reallocate capital towards green investment. While many sources of savings are long term (pension funds and sovereign wealth funds) and the investments needed for the Green Transition are long term, standing in between are short-term financial markets. Local, national, and multilateral Green Development Banks may be helpful in financing the private green transition. Better disclosure to investors of risks associated with “brown” investments (i.e., ones that contribute to pollution) and changes in fiduciary standards for asset managers towards their investors, would help move resources into green investments. Of course, without strong incentives, provided by price signals and environmental regulatory constraints, incentives for green investments and innovation will be greatly attenuated.

IV. Lessons from Past Technological Transformations

To grasp the historical nature of what is going on, it is necessary to put the advent of AI and related technologies in the context of the broader history of technological progress. Humanity spent much of its history at a Malthusian stage. The Industrial Revolution started a little over two centuries ago, and was but a blip in the history of mankind. The era of manufacturing-based export-led growth that enabled the East Asian Miracle stretched over the past half-century – one quarter of the history of the Industrial Revolution. It is easily conceivable that we are now going into another era.

Many are far more sanguine than we are about the disruptive potential of AI. They point to the automobile and other innovations at the end of the nineteenth century. Jobs were lost, making buggy whips and horse carriages obsolete, but overall, labor demand increased, and more jobs were created. Our analytical discussion made clear that there is no inherent reason that innovation has these effects. This time could well be different. Looking at the time before the Industrial Revolution and the early decades of the revolution itself serves as a reminder.

  • A. Pre-Industrial Revolution

Before the Industrial Revolution, innovation proceeded at a far slower pace than today. There were still many innovations, but the actual living standard of the vast majority of people was stagnant ( Maddison, 2003 ). The interpretation of Malthus (1798) was that every time an innovation took place, the population started to grow and absorbed the surplus that was generated.

This pre-industrial state of affairs may be still relevant in the least developed countries and is particularly problematic in some African countries, where the death rate has been greatly reduced by medical innovations, but reproductive rates have continued to be very high. The affected countries have been slow to go through the demographic transition that marked the rise of living standards in Asia. As a result, several countries are facing a difficult-to-manage explosion in population combined with stagnant living standards.

There is a risk that poor countries may see a return to Malthusian dynamics if technological progress undermines the source of their comparative advantage. Consider a country that exports manufacturing goods produced using cheap labor but is not very productive in agriculture, for example because of a shortage of land and a high population density. The country uses its export revenues to import food for workers in the manufacturing sector, granting them a living standard that is above subsistence levels. If a new technology produces the manufacturing goods more cheaply, the wages of the manufacturing workers will fall, and they may well fall below the subsistence cost of workers. If that is the case, the country may return to a Malthusian state of affairs in which part of the population suffers from hunger and deprivation. Increasing agricultural productivity may mitigate this dire state of affairs but the question is, would they be sufficient to support a population that was previously supported by imported food? Thus, populations may decline not as a result of choice, as in many developed countries, but from Malthusian dynamics. In today’s globally connected world, that presents ugly alternatives: Will the rich countries simply look away, as they see this suffering and near-starvation in poorer countries? Will they create ever-increasing barriers to stave off the inevitable pressures of migration?

B. Industrial Revolution

The Industrial Revolution marked the beginning of rapid growth in high-income countries. After centuries in which standards of living had been stagnant, growth started to increase markedly. It transformed the world. The Industrial Revolution thus provides us with a number of lessons that are very relevant today:

  • Innovation Can Be Very Disruptive

Even when an innovation ultimately proves to be beneficial for society at large, not everyone benefits. It can give rise to very large disruptions during the transition. In the short run, there was significant social upheaval from the industrial revolution—Charles Dickens’ novels make it clear that not everyone prospered. In the UK, some people were living under much worse conditions in the cities of the mid-19 th century than they had been in the rural areas prior to that. Even indicators such as life expectancy initially went down. Looking at those who suffered, the Industrial Revolution was clearly not a Pareto improvement.

  • Collective Action Can Mitigate the Adverse Effects

The onset of the industrial revolution posed many challenges that required collective action. However, it took time for societies to put in place the collective mechanisms to respond to these challenges. This is why the industrial revolution had significant negative effects on the masses for some time. Eventually, governments played an important role in mitigating the adverse effects, including the problems posed by urbanization, such as challenges in sanitation, environmental degradation, public health, infrastructure, and congestion.

Government took a strong role too in advancing the positive effects of the new economy. Education was an important element in creating a productive workforce – it was therefore also in the interests of capitalists, and public education received broad public support.

In high-income countries, institutions related to labor legislation, unionization, and social safety nets were not created until the end of the 19 th century and beginning of the 20 th century. In the United States, the ready availability of land implied that labor was relatively scarce, limiting the extent to which labor could be exploited. Nonetheless, in the early years of the 20 th century, labor was not doing very well. It was only dramatic events like the 1911 Triangle Shirtwaist Factory fire in New York City that led to labor legislation that really protected workers. In most high-income countries, labor legislation today is taken for granted, but in 1900, it was not obvious if meaningful labor legislation would ever be enacted. Strikingly, some of the tough political battles that made the adoption of such legislation problematic a century ago are playing out once again in the United States, where there has been an erosion of protections, for example, those associated with minimum wages, health and safety standards, or overtime pay, among others.

These labor market reforms helped support the structural transformation that occurred with the rise of manufacturing, and they showed that equality and growth are complementary (e.g., Ostry et al., 2019 ). At a basic level, they were necessary to sustain social peace and democracy. And they ushered in what might be called an “Age of Labor.” Most developing countries have not gone through this process yet.

This Age of Labor may not last forever. In the US, minimum wages have declined in real terms in recent decades, below the level of fifty years ago ( Figure 6 ), and many protections on hours and working conditions have been eviscerated. Advances in AI may further contribute to undermining labor’s bargaining position and thus these social protections. And in developing countries, they may do so before workers have ever acquired similar levels of rights and protections as they have in high-income countries.

Figure 6.

Federal Minimum Wage (adjusted for inflation) in the US, 1938–2020

  • Politics and Political Economy

The Age of Labor conferred not only unprecedented economic returns upon workers in the form of rising wages, but also, in parallel, unprecedented political power. However, this power has been eroded more recently (see e.g. Boix, 2019 ). In simple models of democracy, the median voter (or more broadly, the “majority”) determines political outcomes. But the evidence is that that model provides a poor description of the outcomes of the political process. For instance, the majority of voters want a more egalitarian society (see, e.g., chapter 1 in Cerra et al., forthcoming ). But in recent decades, in many countries, the political and economic rules have evolved in the opposite direction, giving more influence to the power of “money”. 23 , 24

  • C. Manufacturing-Based Export-Led Growth

In developing countries, there has been a single model of development that has proved enormously successful over the past fifty years: manufacturing-based export-led growth (see Stiglitz, 2018a ). It enabled many East Asian countries to close the gap between themselves and high-income countries, increasing per capita incomes in these countries multifold.

One big change inherent in this development strategy was moving from discussions of static comparative advantage to more dynamic comparative advantage. This was central to the East Asia “Miracle.” Half a century ago, South Korea was seen by many to have a comparative advantage in agriculture. It instead pursued a strategy of creating its own dynamic comparative advantage via an industrial policy that led it towards industrialization. That model served most of East Asia remarkably well, in a way few had anticipated (e.g., Myrdal (1968) who predicted that Asia would never develop). See also Aghion et al. (2021) .

The path to development in East Asia has been via exports of cheap labor-intensive manufactured goods. This development strategy combined learning, the provision of employment opportunities, foreign exchange, tax revenue—everything that was needed for a quick developmental transition.

While their development trajectory began with taking advantage of their static comparative advantage in cheap labor, and especially cheap unskilled labor, over time, many East Asian countries moved up the “value” chain, producing higher value added and more complex products and developing their dynamic comparative advantage.

Earlier advances in technology have already reduced the importance of cheap labor; but now advances in AI may erode it further still. Going forward, growth led solely by exports of labor-intensive manufacturing goods will no longer be available as a strategy of development. Indeed, the share of manufacturing employment is decreasing globally. Moreover, the jobs that can be outsourced may be more easily automated. There may be reshoring of production that had previously been outsourced, using highly automated production processes, and the process may have been accelerated by the Covid pandemic.

The forces that facilitated the development in East Asia may thus be going in reverse, making it difficult for other developing countries to follow the strategy.

One of the critical reasons for the success of the export-led growth model based on manufacturing goods was that it enabled developing countries to catch up in multiple domains. 25 Developing countries are poorer than developed countries not only because there is a gap in material resources but also because of a gap in knowledge ( World Bank, 1998 ). A quarter century ago, the World Bank began thinking of itself as a knowledge bank, not only helping countries to catch up in resources but also to catch up in knowledge.

AI may have characteristics that will increase the gap in knowledge and make it more difficult to catch up. While technology adoption lags have declined over the past centuries ( Comin and Hobijn, 2010 and Figure 7 ), the specific nature of AI may reverse that. Cutting-edge AI technology is highly specialized, and improvements are driven to a large degree by learning from large datasets, creating a winner-takes-all dynamic, as we noted earlier. In addition, a disproportionate share of the people working in AI are in private companies, and a significant share of the knowledge is not in the public domain and therefore not easily accessible to developing and emerging economies. (This contrasts with many past technologies, when publicly financed knowledge production was more central, so access to knowledge was more easily available to developing and emerging economies.) Moreover, an important resource input to AI is data, and access to data is concentrated and not globally public. The implication is that the nature of AI technology and how these advances are generated will make it more difficult to catch up than in the past. In fact, the exponential nature of growth in AI technology may imply that laggards not only cannot catch up, but that the gap between them and the front runners may grow, compounding the potential adverse effects that developing countries may suffer from labor-saving or resource-saving technological progress. 26

Figure 7.

Technology Adoption Lags

  • D. What is Different This Time

Not only may the AI revolution make it more difficult for developing countries to catch up, the AI revolution may also be more difficult to manage for economic policymakers than earlier technological transitions. The structural transformation from an agrarian rural economy to an industrial urban economy eventually led to a more egalitarian society. As we have noted, the reasons included that innovation associated with that transition overall was unskilled-biased, i.e., it increased the relative productivity of unskilled labor. Moreover, industrial production provided a strong force towards mass education. Furthermore, industrial production typically involved large establishments that could be unionized relatively easily, and the unions advocated for wage compression. All these forces led to greater equality. In the current transition, what risks becoming our “destination”—a service sector economy, marked by greater inequality, with less support for public education and more concentrations of market power—may be less attractive in many ways than the current situation, and the process of getting there may be more disruptive; that is, unless countervailing policy interventions are made.

AI may be labor-saving and resource-saving, and it is likely more biased towards ever-higher skills so that general education becomes less important. 27 This may reduce support for equality-enhancing public education, which has been one of the strong forces for more equalitarian outcomes in the past. Moreover, the service sector which is becoming an increasingly important part of the economy is marked by smaller establishments. In addition, worker tenure has declined, making it harder to unionize the workforce ( Choi and Spletzer, 2012 ). Digital technologies are likely to create more barriers to entry and give rise to more monopoly power and winner-takes-all dynamics, with rents going to a small number of extremely wealthy individuals and enterprises, disproportionately located in high-income countries.

Although for many developing countries, average income per capita may increase, large fractions of society may be left behind. Moreover, some developing countries may experience declines in income per capita as innovation erodes their comparative advantage. Unskilled workers in these countries may suffer the most.

Although greater inequality would increase the need for social protection, it may result in a less egalitarian politico-economic equilibrium, as the new concentrations of economic and political power may reduce support for the critical role of government in mitigating the adverse distributional consequences of technological change. (See, e.g., Gilens, 2005.)

V. Domestic Policy Responses

We have seen how economic policy played a critical role in shaping economic outcomes in previous eras of innovation; the same will be true in the case of AI. In this section, we discuss what policy levers can be employed to address the effects of technological disruption, both in developing countries and to protect vulnerable segments in advanced economies. Some of these are similar to what worked in earlier periods of technological change; some are attuned to the special problems posed by AI and labor-replacing innovation. In section 6, we will discuss changes in global policies, norms and rules that would assist developing countries in their response to technological change. In this short paper, we can only touch on a few of the more salient policies.

A. Taxation, Redistribution, and Government Expenditures

Among the critical policies to combat rising inequality are those of taxation and redistribution, with a particularly important role for progressive taxation. However, in recent years, a number of countries have actually made their tax systems more and more regressive. For example, many countries tax the returns to capital and rents (such as land rents, monopoly rents, and other forms of exploitation rents) at lower rates than workers. In the US, the rich pay a lower fraction of their income in taxes than the majority of the population ( Saez and Zucman, 2019 ).

Raising taxes is a particular challenge for developing countries, in which the informal sector is typically much larger than in high-income economies. However, this also means that there is significant scope for developing economies to enhance their tax structures and expenditure systems (e.g., scrapping harmful subsidies and tax exemptions) to build fiscal space for public spending, and improvements in tax capacity. Also, new digital tools and new data may actually give governments new policy tools to increase tax compliance. For example, when an activity becomes intermediated via centralized digital platforms, it becomes easier for governments to access business transactions and levy taxes on them. For example, governments have long found it difficult to monitor and tax the earnings of taxi drivers. But if driving is intermediated via digital platforms, all their earnings – including most tips – are recorded. 28

One of the dilemmas when it comes to taxation and redistribution is that labor-saving technological progress reduces tax revenue from labor – traditionally the most highly taxed factor in the economy – precisely at the time when the need for redistribution rises (see e.g. Korinek, 2020 ). This necessitates that taxation increasingly shifts towards other factors and rents. From the perspective of efficiency, the taxation of rents is particularly desirable ( George, 1879 ). Imposing taxes on fixed factors, such as land, acts like a lump sum tax, and taxing rents generated by market power and political activity may discourage such rent-seeking, enhancing efficiency.

We have argued earlier that technological progress creates winners and losers, and the gains of the winners are quasi-rents that governments may be able to tax without introducing distortions. In particular, some of the monopoly rents of digital giants can be taxed without introducing major distortions into the economy.

In designing tax systems, an important concern is about incidence: the possibility that general equilibrium effects imply that taxes are ultimately borne by other factors and agents than those on whom they are levied, undermining the desired redistributive objectives. For example, a common result in simple models is that capital taxation discourages capital accumulation by capitalists. However, the adverse effects may be more than offset by public investments in human and physical capital (see e.g. Stiglitz, 2018b ). High on the list of what is desirable to tax are “bads” rather than goods, i.e., Pigouvian taxes on activities and goods that create negative externalities, for example, polluting or carbon-emitting goods. This would contribute to the Green Transition in a dual way, not only by providing tax revenue for public investments but also by correcting market prices to reflect the negative externalities. 29

  • Social Protection

If individuals could obtain insurance against the adverse effects of disruptive innovations, then it would be more likely that these innovations would be Pareto improvements ( Korinek and Stiglitz, 2019 ). But such insurance is not available. One of the functions of social insurance is to socialize these risks that otherwise would have been borne by individuals. But in developing countries, systems of social protection are typically less developed, making it even more likely that there be significant groups that are worse off.

  • Universal Basic Income

Many commentators have responded to concerns about the impact of technological progress on employment by advocating a universal basic income (UBI). While proposals differ in their detail, they typically entail that all individuals are paid a UBI independent of their employment or wealth status, and with a level of UBI payments geared above the poverty line. While such programs would imply formidable fiscal costs, and with it, possibly large distortionary taxes, those could be contained if a UBI replaced other social safety programs (such as social security, welfare, or unemployment insurance systems). By doing so, it would also reduce the overall administration costs.

From a global welfare perspective, a global UBI that was truly “universal” as the name suggests, i.e., that covers all citizens of the world equally, would be most desirable, given the potentially large global implications of AI. Currently, access to prototypes of a UBI is exclusive to people who were lucky to be born in specific locations that have the fiscal capacity to afford such programs (e.g., in Alaska where oil revenue is collected in the Alaska Permanent Fund and distributed to the residents of the state). But given the limitations on cross-border transfers that have been the center of attention of this paper, a global UBI is clearly still in the realm of fantasy. 30 , 31

However, in the short- to medium-run, the focus should be on creating jobs for everyone who is able and willing to work, especially in light of the earlier discussion of how much labor will be needed for the Green Transition, to provide services to the young, the sick, and the elderly, and to invest in infrastructure. Governments may have a role to play in helping match the need for work and people willing and able to work. However, while a clear need for a UBI may be in a more distant future, there are other policies that may achieve similar objectives to a UBI. For example, one approach to ensuring a modicum of income for all over the long run, with co-benefits of perhaps increasing social cohesion and solidarity, is shared capital ownership (e.g., Solow, 2009 ): as part of government assistance programs (such as those enacted in the wake of COVID-19 in 2020), firms receiving government help should contribute shares to a sovereign wealth fund—owned by everyone within the nation. Similarly, firms that build on or employ innovations that are based in part on government-funded research should be required to do the same. 32

Starting with Keynes (1931), economists have argued that technological progress and automation would in principle enable people to work less and spend more time on more meaningful activities rather than tedious and repetitive tasks – a point also emphasized, for example, by Varian (2020) . However, this requires either that wages go up in tandem with productivity growth, unlike in recent decades, or that the fruits of progress are shared more widely using transfers. If these questions of distribution can be solved satisfactorily, then individuals could indeed respond to productivity growth by working less without experiencing material losses. There is considerable evidence that many workers would prefer to work less and with more flexible work sessions. The Dutch model, which provides all workers with a right to part-time work (at pro-rated wages) could serve as an example, assuming that wages are sufficiently high. 33 , 34

  • Expenditure and Infrastructure Policy

Expenditure policy can be as important in offsetting the adverse effects of AI as taxation and direct redistribution, and it carries several benefits over transfers that are particularly relevant in developing countries: government expenditures may be easier to target based on need, and for whom the social returns of those expenditures may be high. For instance, expenditures on human well-being, such as on education and health, are naturally targeted to those who need education and healthcare, rather than being spent on those who already are educated or on those who are healthy. Expenditures to protect the environment help those who bear the brunt of environmental degradation, including climate change, which disproportionately affect the poor. 35

Expenditure policies that increase the demand for unskilled labor may serve double duty: they raise demand for unskilled labor, increasing the equality of market income (what is often now called pre-distribution), and sometimes they can be targeted so that the benefits of the expenditure go disproportionately to the less well-off. One important example is infrastructure investments in poorer neighborhoods, which are a labor-intensive expenditure that can be designed to be pro-egalitarian.

Of particular importance are investments in digital infrastructure that reduce the “digital divide” and allow citizens to access the vast services provided by the Internet. Recent advances in network technology allow developing countries to leapfrog older technologies in which high-income countries have invested fortunes, for example by using wireless 5G technologies instead of laying vast networks of cables.

Other infrastructure investments include public transportation systems that connect especially lower income workers with jobs and enhance the opportunities available to them. Another example of labor-demand increasing public expenditures is creating service sector jobs, for example in healthcare, caring for the elderly, and some aspects of education, which can again be designed to serve double duty – disproportionately benefiting the poor and needy as they increase wages by increasing the demand for labor.

B. Pre-Distribution

Our concern here is the distribution of consumption (or more broadly, of well-being) among the citizens of a country. That is affected by inequalities in market incomes and the extent of redistribution. The previous subsection discussed redistribution through tax and expenditure policies. But a society with a more equalitarian market distribution needs to place less burden on redistribution. Good policy entails an optimal mix of “pre-distribution”—actions to increase the equality of market income—and redistribution. This is especially so because some of the actions to increase the equality of market distribution are actually efficiency-enhancing, i.e., have a negative cost. For instance, actions which reduce market power, the ability of firms to exploit information asymmetries, or to engage in a variety of other exploitive practices.

There are two categories of policies which affect the distribution of market incomes: (1) Policies that affect individuals endowments of assets—human capital (education) and financial assets. These are affected by the public provision of education and more broadly, policies which affect the intergenerational transmission of advantage and disadvantage (such as inheritance taxes.) And (2) policies that affect the returns on factors, which include the laws and regulations that determine the “rules of the game.” These include competition laws, labor legislation, and rules governing globalization, the financial sector, and corporate governance. These rules affect simultaneously efficiency and distribution. 36

Education Regarding the first set of such policies, the fact that more educated workers receive higher incomes than less educated ones may invite the conclusion that education is the solution to inequality. While providing more equal access to high-quality education especially for the poor may reduce inequality—and is absolutely essential to avoid an education-based digital divide whereby some simply do not know how to access and benefit from the resources and opportunities offered by the Internet and related digital technologies—education is far from a panacea. Indeed, if there are large innate differences in ability, education can identify and amplify these differences, actually increasing inequalities in market income. ( Stiglitz, 1975b ). Moreover, education cannot address the problems arising from the declining share of labor income overall.

  • Steering Innovation in AI in High-income Countries

The overall direction of innovation in AI will be set to a large extent by high-income countries plus China. This implies that the direction of technological progress in those countries – how labor-saving it is – also matters for developing countries that will be exposed to the new technologies.

Korinek and Stiglitz (2020) make the case for actively steering technological progress so that it is more labor-using. They show that whenever lump-sum transfers are not available, it is desirable to encourage technological progress that leads to higher demand for those types of workers with the lowest incomes. This can be done by nudging entrepreneurs, by considering the labor market implications of government-sponsored research, or by explicit incentives provided to the private sector. Klinova and Korinek (2021) and Partnership on AI (2021) describe how to develop and how to operationalize frameworks for steering advances in AI towards greater shared prosperity.

Many governmental policies have indirect effects on incentives for innovation. For example, at least in the short run, the cost of capital is influenced by monetary policy, with the goal of stabilizing aggregate demand. In recent years, monetary authorities in many countries have set interest rates such that real returns on safe assets have been very low or even negative, likely below the social shadow price of capital. Stiglitz (2014) shows that this encourages excessive automation in high-income countries. Acemoglu et al (2020) observe that tax policies that favor capital over labor also distort the direction of progress towards saving labor.

And there are immediate implications for developing countries: Once the cost of developing a labor-saving innovation has been incurred in high-income countries, it can frequently be rolled out globally at comparatively low cost, potentially imposing significant welfare costs on workers in developing countries. Examples include self-checkout kiosks that harm workers, whatever their benefits or costs may be for consumers and global corporates.

Pritchett (2019) observes that migration policies in high-income countries restrict labor supply and lead to comparatively high wages that do not reflect the abundance of labor, and in particular of unskilled labor, at the global level. The high wages then provide innovators in high-income countries with excessive incentives to invest in the automation of tasks that are performed by unskilled labor compared to what is desirable from the perspective of developing countries (or from the perspective of global efficiency). 37

Economists are also becoming increasingly aware of the importance of regional heterogeneity. Unlike in stylized models in which only national borders exist, labor does not move seamlessly across regions within countries. Even in high-income countries, large disparities between regions or between rural and urban areas persist, as illustrated, for example, by the case of northern and southern Italy or by the rural/urban differential in the United States and many other countries. Looking ahead, the “good” jobs of the future (e.g., those hard to automate and/or complementary to AI) might be located in major urban centers (such as non-routine manual occupations and personal services). Such geographical disparities call for location-based policies in fostering development, although the details of such policies can be complex. For example, they may entail a trade-off between income growth (which benefits from geographical concentration) and geographical inequality (which does not).

  • New Development Strategies

Developing countries will need a new multi-pronged development strategy to replace the manufacturing-led export-based growth model. Industrial policies have traditionally been among the most important aspects of countries’ development strategies—interventions that shape the direction in which the economy is moving, with particular emphasis on the secondary sector. However, in an age of increasing automation in manufacturing, development strategies have to broaden their focus beyond manufacturing and the secondary sector to other sectors of the economy, including agriculture and services. 38

Greenwald and Stiglitz (2014b) point out that every country has, in effect, a sectoral development policy—shaped by infrastructure and education investments and tax and regulatory policy. It is only that some countries do not know (or admit) that they have such policies. The danger then is that such policies can be more easily captured by special interests. 39 In developing countries development policies are much more at the center of economic policy. They need to be designed to manage innovations and mitigate the effects of and adapt to the disruptions that innovations may engender, to ensure that the net societal benefits, broadly defined, are maximized.

A lot of innovation in developing countries focuses on technology adoption and adaptation rather than developing entirely novel technologies. Whereas high-income countries focus on “steering innovation,” developing countries need to pay attention to “steering the adoption of technologies.” Their development strategy should intentionally focus on steering the adoption of labor-using technologies that have already been developed in high-income countries, adapting them to their own circumstances and needs, redesigning them, and building on them. Decisions on what type of inward FDI to encourage should also be informed by these objectives.

In designing the new development strategies, developing countries will need to think carefully about the rationale for public interventions: how can government improve upon the decisions made by decentralized agents? Of particular importance is that the direction of technological progress and technology adoption is endogenous, and there is no presumption that market decisions in this area are socially desirable. Decisions made at one date have effects in later periods, with firms making the decisions appropriating only a fraction of the benefits and bearing only part of the costs of their decisions. For example, this is clearly manifest when there are knowledge spillovers to other firms and when technology evolves over time, e.g., through learning by doing. Firms acting on their own will not fully consider the dynamic implications of their decisions today on others.

There are also market failures beyond the ability to appropriate the returns from current choices—for instance, imperfections of risk and capital markets. The capital market imperfections that impede the reallocation of labor in high-income countries in response to innovation—and that can result in innovations which decrease welfare —are even more important in developing countries, making it imperative to combine industrial policies with active labor market policies (see, e.g., delli Gati et al., 2012a, 2012b).

Relatedly, part of the problem is that market prices do not adequately reflect social shadow values. A well-known example is that, in the absence of appropriate regulation, the price of carbon in the market is zero, but this does not reflect the social cost of carbon. Similarly, market prices do not reflect the social value of an equitable distribution of resources and do not guide innovation in that direction. Given the constraints on redistribution, this leaves an important role for the government to steer innovation and foster economic development in a socially desirable direction ( Korinek and Stiglitz, 2020 ). For example, much could be gained from encouraging innovators to shift their focus from labor-saving towards more labor-using technologies.

Fortunately, while the new technologies necessitate a change away from the old and highly successful development strategies of the past half century, they also open up new opportunities. In agriculture, AI offers the potential for large productivity increases based on algorithms that help farmers fine-tune and optimize a range of decisions that increase their yield. Such algorithms depend on crops, soil and weather conditions and need to be customized to local conditions. Just as agricultural extension services, which extended general knowledge about agriculture to local farmers, played a critical role in the development of the US, there is an important role for government agricultural extension services today in developing countries. 40 Digital platforms can also enhance the ability of small farmers to trade their products at fair market prices, reducing the market power of middle men that frequently absorb a significant fraction of the surplus generated in agriculture.

Developing the service sector is crucial for economic development as the role of the primary and secondary sectors is declining. Many developing countries may carve out new areas of comparative advantage in services that will, however, depend on good internet connections and a certain degree of education of the workforce. For example, call centers and similar business and consumer services rely on requisite language skills. There is also a growing market for simple human services that can be broken down into small components and fed into AI systems (e.g., labeling images). However, as we noted earlier, services that can be outsourced are often also more easily automated. Other services such as tourism have proven a more automation-resistant (although not pandemic-resistant) source of export revenue for countries that have managed to fashion themselves into desirable tourist destinations. Exporting services offers many of the potential growth benefits of the manufacturing-based export-led growth model.

Services that are aimed at a domestic audience, for example, healthcare, caring for the elderly, as well as education, may not deliver much export revenue but are important for economic development and welfare. There is much scope for employing AI to improve the delivery and efficiency of these services, and it requires government policy to do so since private service providers are frequently small in size and cannot afford the necessary investments. And even in these areas, there may be significant opportunities for cross border trade, for example, via medical tourism and via retirees from advanced countries relocating to warmer climates, if adequate health care is available.

VI. Global Governance

In a globally integrated economy—from which developing countries and emerging markets have benefited enormously in many ways—global rules matter. The global rules have always been set to favor high-income countries; they are, to a large extent, set by the large powerful countries, and frequently by powerful special interests within them, whereas developing countries do not have a seat at the table, or are at least underrepresented.

The global rules have large effects on the ability of these countries to levy taxes in the digital era, on high-income countries’ ability to extract rents from the developing countries (say through market power and intellectual property rights), and more broadly on the global terms of trade and distribution of income. 41 While developing countries may realize these inequities—and the inefficiencies—of our global economic system, it often seems that there is little they can do.

AI has provided a new arena in which rules need to be set, at the same time that it may exacerbate the imbalances in economic power, as our earlier discussion emphasized. However, there are reasons for cautious hope when it comes to the rules governing information and AI. First, the rules in this area are still in the process of being set so there is hope that international institutions and civil society may have a positive impact on the shape of these rules. Still, the fact that recent trade agreements between the US and other countries have contained provisions reflecting the interests of big-tech companies—with limited open debate and limiting the scope for these trading partners to design regimes that reflect a broader public interest—is of concern.

Secondly, it should be in the self-interest of high-income countries to avoid the possibility of a strong backlash to globalization in developing countries. The possibility of such a backlash is considerable: The United States and a number of other high-income countries, which have been big beneficiaries of globalization, have experienced such a backlash – in part because they have not ensured that the losers of globalization were compensated. In the past, there was at least some sense that globalization created mutual gains for high-income and developing countries. The backlash in developing countries would be even greater if they come to see globalization as a mechanism of rent extraction from their economies (even if the truth may be that technological change is making them lose some of the earlier gains from globalization).

Moreover, international institutions, some of which are less and less dominated by high-income countries, may play a role in ensuring that the rules are set in a way that more adequately reflects the interests and concerns of all countries, including developing countries. As the rules for new technologies are being written, there are several areas of particular concern in which reforms in global governance would help developing countries better adapt to advances in AI.

  • A. A Global Tax Regime for the Digital Age

The inadequacies in the global tax regime make it difficult for developing countries to capture much of the rents that the global digital giants earn within their borders, even as their activities take away business from domestic firms and thereby reduce the domestic tax base. Indeed, even high-income countries have had difficulty with adequately taxing global tech giants. Some of the issues are now being discussed at the OECD in an attempt to establish a global tax regime.

The current global tax regime allows multinational firms to avoid much taxation—often paying taxes at rates markedly lower than local small businesses. It also impairs the ability of developing countries and emerging markets to tax the economic activity which occurs within their territories. This system is both inefficient and inequitable.

The controversy over digital taxation has exposed the deeper problems of multinational corporate taxation based on transfer prices, which are easily manipulated. The issue could be addressed by moving to a formulary apportionment system, whereby the worldwide profits of a corporation are apportioned to different countries according to a formula (see, e.g., Clausing and Avi-Yonah, 2007 ). The exact formula could have large distributive effects across countries. For instance, a simple formula based just on sales, while less manipulatable than other formulae, may disadvantage developing countries. A particular controversy associated with the digital economy is the value assigned to the data that are collected in the process of economic transactions and how and whether that value should be taxed.

The broader debate over international taxation has also led to renewed attention on closing down fiscal paradises, on international initiatives for transparency in capital ownership, which would help developing countries to increase their tax base, and on creating a global minimum multinational corporate tax rate, to prevent a race to the bottom.

  • B. Global Competition Policy

The tendency of digital technologies to give rise to natural monopolies makes competition policy especially important. One challenge is that the countries in which tech giants are based have incentives to protect their own tech firms since they share in the rents that these firms earn globally. For example, when the European Union investigated Google for anticompetitive practices or when Germany investigated the privacy practices of Facebook, the US treated it as a political question rather than a matter of economic policy and responded by accusing Europe of being anti-American. While the policy remedies suggested by the Europeans may have reduced the rents the companies could earn in Europe, their purported aim was to ascertain that these firms’ practices did not violate the norms on competition and privacy established in Europe. The tendency for matters of competition policy to turn into arguments over rents may get worse, given the global concentration of market power in AI in two countries, China and the United States.

Individual developing countries and emerging market economies stand little chance in reining in the behaviors of powerful global corporations on their own – in many instances, the corporations have a higher market capitalization than the GDP of the countries in question. This makes it important for developing countries to coordinate and develop competition policy together, for example, via a common competition authority for developing and emerging economies that can exert sufficient power over large global corporations, just as the countries of Europe would not be able to police the competitive behavior of American corporations on their own but are able to do so through the European Union.

Given the breadth and reach of the new digital giants, there is a need for stronger rules preventing conflicts of interest for companies that simultaneously own a marketplace and participate in it, and stronger rules preventing pre-emptive mergers, i.e., mergers and acquisitions designed to stifle the threat of a competitive marketplace in the future. There will also be a need for more ex-post remediation: breaking up mergers when they prove to be anti-competitive. 42 As the experiences cited above have shown, the countries in which digital giants are based may not have the correct incentives to police these companies’ competitive practices, given the large global rents that are at stake.

  • C. Intellectual Property Rights

The current system of intellectual property (IP) rights is designed to give (temporary) monopoly rents to innovators to compensate and reward them for their innovative activities. There has been much concern in recent years that the prevailing IP system gives excessive protection to innovators, with particularly adverse effects on developing countries. As the World Commission on the Social Dimensions of Globalization (2004) emphasized, there is a need to rebalance the international IP regime to ensure an equitable distribution of the gains from technological progress. Korinek and Stiglitz (2019) demonstrated that reducing the length of patent protection can ensure that the gains from AI-based innovations are better shared among society and can thus lead to a welfare improvement.

The most efficient way of distributing technological advances is to keep them in the public domain, financed via governments, international organizations, donors or charities. This avoids restrictions in access to new technologies and the creation of monopolies that concentrate rents and power. There is much scope for publicly financed research and development to benefit developing countries, for example, in the areas of agriculture where new technologies increase the productivity of crops, or in healthcare where developing countries face unique challenges that do not attract sufficient research by private corporations in high-income countries.

When research and development is financed privately, there is a strong case for granting different patent protection in developing countries than in high-income economies. The length of patent protection trades off how much surplus to allocate to innovators to compensate them for their efforts versus how much to let the broader public benefit from an innovation. Most patents are developed in high-income countries and are financed by the surplus that innovators extract from the patent protection there; innovators would not incur significant losses if developing countries could use their technology for free before their patents expire in high-income countries. Indeed, in many sectors, including pharmaceuticals, there is extensive cross-border price discrimination; drug companies could offer life-saving drugs to some of the poorest countries at steeply discounted prices. Compulsory licenses (part of TRIPS and other international agreements) give the right to access such life-saving IP at appropriate royalties, but many developing countries do not have the capacity to exercise those rights; and those that do have the capacity are intimidated from doing so by threats from developed countries. Trade agreements have done everything they can to impede access to generic medicines, forcing developing countries to pay high prices for drugs.

Before the advent of AI, it was clear that there was a need for a developmentally oriented IP regime—in some ways markedly different from that currently prevailing ( Cimoli et al 2014 ). But AI has made the challenge of access to knowledge even greater. Part of the nature of AI is that it may not even need much protection by the patent system. Algorithms can be kept proprietary, and they are always evolving. Requiring disclosure of certain key algorithms is imperative to ascertain whether algorithms are discriminatory, for example, by engaging in price discrimination. 43

  • D. Data and Information Policy

Data is a critical input underlying the new AI economy. That is why information policy – the rules governing the control over and use of data – has moved to the top of the policy agenda. Global tech firms are setting the data regulatory agenda in their interest without sufficient public oversight. This has already happened in recent trade agreements. For instance, while the new trade agreement between Canada, Mexico and the US had stronger provisions protecting labor and access to healthcare as well as better investor-state dispute settlement provisions, rules on the digital economy moved in the opposite direction, providing better protection for the tech giants. Being part of an international agreement, it may be difficult to change the data regulation regime in the future. This is particularly important for developing countries: the rules are currently being set with little concern for the views of citizens in the high-income countries, let alone those in the rest of the world.

Moreover, the monopolization of data by global AI firms also makes it more difficult for developing countries to catch up and develop their own AI-based companies. Global firms can use their access to vast troves of data from across the world to refine their products and offerings to consumers ever further. This makes it more and more difficult for newcomers in developing countries to close the gap between themselves and the leading firms.

Europe has actively worked on rules to ensure that the benefits of new digital technologies are shared and the harms are minimized. For instance, the EU has put forward proposals to require data sharing, with the goal of preventing accretion of monopoly power by monopolizing data. But giving control rights over data to individuals will not suffice; without proper regulation, individuals turn their data over to the digital giants and internet providers, receiving but a pittance: asymmetries in information and power are just too great to ensure an equitable outcome.

New transparency regulations, for example, regarding the algorithms and targeting of advertising, are necessary, but again not sufficient. Policymakers must be able to address the discriminatory impacts of pricing and advertising.

There is also a need for stronger rules protecting privacy and the rapid spread of misinformation and messages that promote violence and hate as well as other harmful messaging, even when conducted as part of a political campaign. In the US, the Section 230 provision which reduces the accountability of internet companies—unlike other publishers— is an example of a regulation that should be reconsidered.

As in the case of competition policy, the countries in which tech giants are based may not face the correct incentives to police the worldwide behavior of their companies since they share in the rents that these companies earn around the world. Developing countries need to cooperate and band together to have sufficient clout to impose regulation on global giants that reflects their developmental interests.

  • VII. Conclusion

Advances in AI and related technologies may, like the Industrial Revolution, represent a critical turning point in history. Increasing automation in manufacturing may lead to increases in wage inequality, declining labor demand, and increased skill premia in most countries; as well as to the demise of the manufacturing-export-led developmental model, which has historically had profound positive effects on many emerging market economies. The worst-case scenario is the unravelling of much of the gains in development and poverty reduction that could be observed over the last half century.

While earlier technological advances were associated with more shared prosperity and increasing equality between and within countries, the new advances may result in increasing inequality along both dimensions unless policies are designed to counterbalance them.

The new era will be governed by different rules and will require a different kind of economic analysis. Just as the production functions that Ricardo used to analyze agrarian and rural economies are very different from those in the models of a manufacturing economy that dominated the mid-20 th century, current economic frameworks must be adjusted and updated to think about the models that will describe the next 50 years. For instance, the competitive equilibrium model may be even less relevant to the 21 st century AI economy than it was to the 20 th century manufacturing economy.

There is a particular high degree of uncertainty across the possible scenarios of technological development and their impact, but what we do know is that there are large potential downside risks that should not be ignored. Economic analysis, based on models appropriate to this new era, has the potential to help in the development of policies—both at the global and national level—that can mitigate these adverse effects, to ensure that this new era of innovation will lead to increased standards of living for all, including the billions living in developing countries.

Acemoglu , Daron ( 1998 ), “ Why Do New Technologies Complement Skills? Directed Technical Change and Wage Inequality ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , 113 ( 4 ), pp. 1055 – 1089 .

  • Search Google Scholar
  • Export Citation

Acemoglu , Daron ( 2002 ), “ Directed Technical Change ,” Review of Economic Studies , 69 ( 4 ), pp. 781 – 809 .

Acemoglu , Daron and David Autor ( 2011 ), “ Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings ,” Handbook of Labor Economics 4b , pp. 1043 – 1171 .

Acemoglu , Daron , Andrea Manera , and Pascual Restrepo ( 2020 ), “ Does the US tax code favor automation? ” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2020 ( 1 ).

Acemoglu , Daron , and Pascual Restrepo ( 2019a ), “ Automation and New Tasks: How Technology Displaces and Reinstates Labor ,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33 ( 2 ), pp. 3 – 30 .

Acemoglu , Daron , and Pascual Restrepo ( 2019b ), “ Demographics and Automation ,” Unpublished Working Paper, MIT . https://economics.mit.edu/files/16788

Acemoglu , Daron , and Pascual Restrepo ( 2020 ), “ Robots and Jobs: Evidence from US Labor Markets ,” Journal of Political Economy 128 ( 6 ), pp. 2188 – 2244 .

Aghion , Philippe , Ufuk Akcigit , Antonin Bergeaud , Richard Blundell , and David Hemous ( 2019 ), “ Innovation and Top Income Inequality ,” Review of Economic Studies 86 ( 1 ), pp. 1 – 45 .

Aghion , Philippe , Reda Cherif , and Fuad Hasanov ( 2021 ), “ Competition, Innovation, and Inclusive Growth ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2021/080. Also forthcoming as Chapter 6 in Cerra et al. (forthcoming) .

Aghion , Philippe , Benjamin F. Jones & Charles I. Jones ( 2017 ), “ Artificial Intelligence and Economic Growth ,” NBER WP 23928 .

Akcigit , Ufuk , Wenjie Chen , Federico J. Díez , Romain Duval , Philipp Engler , Jiayue Fan , Chiara Maggi , Marina M. Tavares , Daniel Schwarz , Ippei Shibata , and Carolina Villegas-Sánchez ( 2021 ), “ Rising Corporate Market Power: Emerging Policy Issues ,” IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/21/01 .

Alonso , Cristian , Andrew Berg , Siddharth Kothari , Chris Papageorgiou , and Sidra Rehman ( 2020 ), “ Will the AI Revolution Cause a Great Divergence? ,” IMF Working Paper 20/184 .

Armstrong , Stuart , Kaj Sotala and Seán S. ÓhÉigeartaigh ( 2014 ), “ The errors, insights and lessons of famous AI predictions – and what they mean for the future ,” Journal of Experimental & Theoretical Artificial Intelligence , 26 ( 3 ), pp. 317 – 342 . http://www.fhi.ox.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/FAIC.pdf

Arrow , Kenneth ( 1962a ), “ Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention ,” in: R. Nelson , ed., The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors , Princeton University Press .

Arrow , Kenneth ( 1962b ), “ The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing ,” The Review of Economic Studies 29 ( 3 ), pp. 155 – 173 .

Atkinson , Anthony , and Joseph Stiglitz ( 1969 ), “ A New View of Technological Change ,” Economic Journal 79 ( 315 ), pp. 573 – 578

Autor , David H. , ( 2014 ), “ Skills, Education, and the Rise of Earnings Inequality Among the ’Other 99 Percent’ ,” Science , 23 May 2014 : 344 ( 6186 ), pp. 843 – 851 .

Autor , David ( 2015 ), “ Why Are There Still So Many Jobs? The History and Future of Workplace Automation ,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 29 ( 3 ), pp. 3 – 30 .

Autor , David H. ( 2019 ), “ Work of the Past, Work of the Future ,” AEA Papers and Proceedings 109 , pp. 1 – 32 .

Autor , David , David Dorn , Lawrence F Katz , Christina Patterson , and John Van Reenen ( 2020 ), “ The Fall of the Labor Share and the Rise of Superstar Firms ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 135 ( 2 ), pp. 645 – 709 .

Autor , David , Frank Levy , and Richard J. Murnane , ( 2003 ), “ The Skill Content of Recent Technological Change: An Empirical Exploration ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 ( 4 ), pp. 1279 – 1333 .

Berg , Andrew , Edward F. Buffie , and Luis-Felipe Zanna ( 2018 ), “ Should we fear the robot revolution? (The correct answer is yes) ,” Journal of Monetary Economics 97 , pp. 117 – 148 .

Boix , Carles ( 2019 ), Democratic Capitalism at the Crossroads: Technological Change and the Future of Politics , Princeton University Press .

Brussevich , Mariya , Era Dabla-Norris , Christine Kamunge , Pooja Karnane , Salma Khalid , and Kalpana Kochhar ( 2018 ), “ Gender, Technology, and the Future of Work ,” IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/18/07, October 2018 .

Brynjolfsson , Erik , Avinash Collis , Erwin Diewert , Felix Eggers , and Kevin Fox ( 2020 ), “ Measuring the Impact of Free Goods on Real Household Consumption ,” AEA Papers and Proceedings 110 , pp. 25 – 30 .

Brynjolfsson , Erik , Daniel Rock , and Chad Syverson ( 2019 ), “ Artificial Intelligence and the Modern Productivity Paradox: A Clash of Expectations and Statistics ,” The Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda, Agrawal, Gans, and Goldfarb .

Caselli , Francesco , and Alan Manning ( 2019 ), “ Robot Arithmetic: New Technology and Wages ,” American Economic Review: Insights 2019 1 ( 1 ), pp. 1 – 12 .

Cerra , Valerie , Barry Eichengreen , Asmaa El-Ganainy , and Martin Schindler (Eds.) (forthcoming), How to Achieve Inclusive Growth , Oxford University Press and IMF .

Charlton , Andrew , and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2005 ), Fair Trade for All , Oxford University Press .

Choi , Eleanor J. , and James R. Spletzer ( 2012 ), “ The declining average size of establishments: evidence and explanations ,” BLS Monthly Labor Review, March 2012 . https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2012/03/art4full.pdf

Cimoli , Mario , Giovanni Dosi , Keith E. Maskus , Ruth L. Okediji , Jerome H. Reichman , and Joseph Stiglitz (eds.) ( 2014 ), Intellectual Property Rights: Legal and Economic Challenges for Development , Oxford University Press

Clausing , Kimberley and Reuben Avi-Yonah ( 2007 ), “ Reforming Corporate Taxation in a Global Economy: A Proposal to Adopt Formulary Apportionment ,” The Hamilton Project, Brookings Institution .

Colmer , Jonathan , Ian Hardman , Jay Shimshack , and John Voorheis ( 2020 ), “ Disparities in PM2.5 air pollution in the United States ,” Science , Vol. 369 , Issue 6503 , pp. 575 – 578 .

Comin , Diego , and Bart Hobijn ( 2010 ), “ An Exploration of Technology Diffusion ,” American Economic Review 100 ( 5 ), pp. 2031 – 59 .

Delli Gatti , Domenico , Mauro Gallegati , Bruce Greenwald , Alberto Russo , and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2012a ), “ Sectoral Imbalances and Long Run Crises ,”The Global Macro Economy and Finance , Franklin Allen, Masahiko Aoki, Jean-Paul Fitoussi, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Roger Gordon, and Joseph Stiglitz, eds., IEA Conference Volume No. 150-III, Palgrave, pp. 61 – 97 .

Delli Gatti , Domenico , Mauro Gallegati , Bruce Greenwald , Alberto Russo , and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2012b ), “ Mobility Constraints, Productivity Trends, and Extended Crises ,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 83 ( 3 ), pp. 375 – 393 .

Ding , Jeffrey , Paul Triolo , and Samm Sacks ( 2018 ), “ Chinese Interests Take a Big Seat at the AI Governance Table ,” New America blog, June 20, 2018 . https://www.newamerica.org/cybersecurity-initiative/digichina/blog/chinese-interests-take-big-seat-ai-governance-table/

El-Ganainy , Asmaa , Ekkehard Ernst , Rossana Merola , Richard Rogerson , and Martin Schindler ( 2021 ), “ Inclusivity in the Labor Market ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2021/141. Also forthcoming as Chapter 3 in Cerra et al. (forthcoming) .

Frey , Carl Benedikt and Michael A. Osborne ( 2017 ), “ The future of employment: How susceptible are jobs to computerisation? ” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 114 , pp. 254 – 280 .

George , Henry ( 1879 ), Progress and poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depressions, and of increase of want with increase of wealth, the remedy , D Appleton and Company .

Good , Irving John ( 1965 ), “ Speculations Concerning the First Ultraintelligent Machine ,” Advances in Computers , Vol. 6 .

Gordon , Robert ( 2016 ), The Rise and Fall of American Growth: The U.S. Standard of Living since the Civil War , Princeton University Press .

Grace , Katja , John Salvatier , Allan Dafoe , Baobao Zhang , and Owain Evans ( 2018 ), “ When Will AI Exceed Human Performance? Evidence from AI Experts ,” Journal of Artificial Intelligence Research , https://arxiv.org/abs/1705.08807v3 .

Greenwald , Bruce and Joseph Stiglitz ( 1986 ) “ Externalities in Economies with Imperfect Information and Incomplete Markets ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , Vol. 101 , No. 2 , May, pp. 229 – 264 .

Greenwald , Bruce and Joseph Stiglitz ( 2006 ) “ Helping Infant Economies Grow: Foundations of Trade Policies for Developing Countries ,” American Economic Review: AEA Papers and Proceedings 96 ( 2 ), pp. 141 – 146 .

Greenwald , Bruce and Joseph Stiglitz ( 2014a ), Creating a Learning Society: A New Approach to Growth, Development, and Social Progress , Columbia University Press .

Greenwald , Bruce and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2014b ), “ Industrial Policies, the Creation of a Learning Society, and Economic Development ,” The Industrial Policy Revolution I: The Role of Government Beyond Ideology , Joseph E. Stiglitz and Justin Yifu Lin (eds.), Palgrave Macmillan , pp. 43 – 71 .

Harari , Yuval Noah ( 2017 ), Homo Deus: A Brief History of Tomorrow , Harper .

Harris , Karen , Austin Kimson , and Andrew Schwedel ( 2018 ), “ Labor 2030: The Collision of Demographics, Automation and Inequality ,” Bain and Company Reports .

Kennedy , Charles ( 1964 ), “ Induced Bias in Innovation and the Theory of Distribution ,” Economic Journal LXXIV , pp. 541 – 47 .

Klinova , Katya and Anton Korinek ( 2021 ), “ AI and Shared Prosperity ,” Proceedings of the 2021 AAAI/ACM Conference on AI, Ethics, and Society (AIES ’21) .

Korinek , Anton ( 2019 ), “ The Rise of Artificially Intelligent Agents ,” working paper , University of Virginia .

Korinek , Anton ( 2020 ), “ Taxation and the Vanishing Labor Market in the Age of AI ,” Ohio State Technology Law Journal 16 ( 1 ), pp. 244 – 257 .

Korinek , Anton and Megan Juelfs ( 2021 ), “ Preparing for the (Non-Existent?) Future of Work ,” in preparation for Justin Bullock et al. (Eds.), Oxford Handbook of AI Governance , Oxford University Press .

Korinek , Anton and Ding Xuan Ng ( 2019 ), “ Digitization and the Macro-Economics of Superstars ,” working paper , University of Virginia .

Korinek , Anton and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2019 ), “ Artificial Intelligence and Its Implications for Income Distribution and Unemployment ,” in Agrawal et al.: The Economics of Artificial Intelligence , NBER and University of Chicago Press .

Korinek , Anton and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2020 ), “ Steering Technological Progress ,” working paper .

Korinek , Anton and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2021a ), “ Artificial Intelligence, Globalization, and Strategies for Economic Development ,” NBER Working Paper w28453 .

Korinek , Anton and Joseph E. Stiglitz ( 2021b ), “ Will COVID-19 Drive Advances in Automation and AI that Exacerbate Economic Inequality?” BMJ 372:n367 .

Kurzweil , Ray ( 2005 ) The Singularity is Near , Penguin Group , pp. 135 – 136 .

Louie , Edward P. , and Joshua M. Pearce ( 2016 ), “ Retraining investment for U.S. transition from coal to solar photovoltaic employment ,” Energy Economics 57 , pp. 295 – 302 .

Maddison , Angus ( 2003 ), Contours of the World Economy 1–2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic History , Oxford University Press .

Malthus , Thomas R. ( 1798 ), An Essay on the Principle of Population , J. Johnson .

McKinsey Global Institute ( 2017 ), “ Jobs lost, jobs gained: What the future of work will mean for jobs, skills, and wages ,” McKinsey Reports .

McMillan , Margaret S. , and Dani Rodrik ( 2011 ), “ Globalization, Structural Change and Productivity Growth ,” NBER Working Paper 17143 .

Myrdal , Gunnar ( 1968 ), Asian Drama: An Inquiry into the Poverty of Nations , Pantheon Books .

Nordhaus , William ( 2015 ), “ Are We Approaching an Economic Singularity? Information Technology and the Future of Economic Growth ,” NBER Working Paper No. 21547 .

OECD ( 2019 ), The Future of Work , OECD Employment Outlook 2019 .

Ostry , Jonathan , Prakash Loungani , and Andrew Berg ( 2019 ), Confronting Inequality: How Societies Can Choose Inclusive Growth , Columbia University Press .

Partnership on AI ( 2021 ), Redesigning AI for Shared Prosperity: An Agenda . Technical Report . Available at: partnershiponai.org/shared-prosperity

Peralta-Alva , Adrian , and Agustin Roitman ( 2018 ), “ Technology and the Future of Work ,” IMF Working Paper WP/18/207. Also published as IMF Staff Note to Group of Twenty: April 2018 .

Peszko , Grzegorz; van der Mensbrugghe , Dominique; Golub , Alexander; Ward , John; Zenghelis , Dimitri; Marijs , Cor; Schopp , Anne; Rogers , John A. l Midgley , Amelia ( 2020 ). Diversification and Cooperation in a Decarbonizing World: Climate Strategies for Fossil Fuel-Dependent Countries . Washington, DC : World Bank .

Peterson Institute for International Economics (PIIE) ( 2020 ), “ How to Fix Economic Inequality? ” https://www.piie.com/sites/default/files/documents/how-to-fix-economic-inequality.pdf .

Pouokam , Nathalie ( 2021 ), “ Sharing Resource Wealth and Addressing Fragility ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2021/097. Also forthcoming as Chapter 6 in Cerra et al. (forthcoming) .

Pritchett , Lant ( 2019 ), “ The Future of Jobs is Facing One, Maybe Two, of the Biggest Price Distortions Ever ,” Economic Research Forum Working Paper 1370 . https://erf.org.eg/app/uploads/2019/12/1370.pdf

Rodrik , Dani ( 2011 ), “ Unconditional Convergence ,” NBER Working Paper w17546 .

Romer , Paul M. ( 1986 ), “ Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth ,” Journal of Political Economy , Vol. 94 , No. 5 ( October ), pp. 1002 – 1037 .

Rubin , Richard ( 2020 ), “ The ’Robot Tax’ Debate Heats Up ,” Wall Street Journal , January 20, 2020 . https://www.wsj.com/articles/the-robot-tax-debate-heats-up-11578495608.

Sacks , Samms ( 2018 ), “ Beijing Wants to Rewrite the Rules of the Internet ,” The Atlantic , June 18, 2018 . https://amp.theatlantic.com/amp/article/563033/

Saez , Emmanuel and Gabriel Zucman ( 2019 ), The Triumph of Injustice: How the Rich Dodge Taxes and How to Make Them Pay , Norton .

Samuelson , Paul ( 1965 ), “ A Theory of Induced Innovations along Kennedy-Weisäcker Lines ,” Review of Economics and Statistics XLVII: 444 – 64 .

Shapiro , Carl and J. E. Stiglitz ( 1984 ) “ Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device ,” American Economic Review , 74 ( 3 ), June 1984 , pp. 433 – 444 .

Solow , Robert ( 1987 ), “ We’d Better Watch Out .” New York Times Book Review , July 12 , pp. 36 .

Solow , Robert ( 2009 ), “ Does Growth Have a Future? Does Growth Theory Have a Future? Are These Questions Related? ,” History of Political Economy 41 , pp. 27 – 34

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 1975a ) “ Information and Economic Analysis ,” Current Economic Problems , J.M. Parkin and A.R. Nobay (eds.), Cambridge : Cambridge University Press , pp. 27 – 52 . ( Proceedings of the Association of University Teachers of Economics, Manchester, England, April 1974 .)

Stiglitz , Joseph ( 1975b ) “ The Theory of Screening, Education and the Distribution of Income ,” American Economic Review , 65 ( 3 ), June 1975, pp. 283 – 300

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 1987a ) “ On the Microeconomics of Technical Progress ,” Technology Generation in Latin American Manufacturing Industries , Jorge M. Katz (ed.), New York : St. Martin’s Press , pp. 56 – 77 . ( Presented to IDB-CEPAL Meetings, Buenos Aires, November 1978 .)

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 1987b ) “ Learning to Learn, Localized Learning and Technological Progress ,” Economic Policy and Technological Performance , P. Dasgupta and Stoneman (eds.), Cambridge University Press , 1987 , pp. 125 – 153 .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2006 ), “ Samuelson and the Factor Bias of Technological Change ,” Samuelsonian Economics and the Twenty-First Century , M. Szenberg et al, eds., Oxford University Press : New York , pp. 235 – 251

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2013 ) The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers Our Future , New York : W.W. Norton & Company .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2014 ), “ Unemployment and Innovation ,” NBER Working Paper no. 20670 .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2015 ), “ Leaders and followers: Perspectives on the Nordic model and the economics of innovation ,” Journal of Public Economics, Elsevier , 127 ( C ), pp 3 – 16 .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2018a ), “ From Manufacturing-Led Export Growth To A Twenty-First-Century Inclusive Growth Strategy: Explaining The Demise Of A Successful Growth Model And What To Do About It ,” WIDER Working Paper 2018/176 Helsinki: UNU-WIDER , accessible at https://www.wider.unu.edu/publication/manufacturing-led-export-growth-twenty-first-century-inclusive-growth-strategy

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2018b ), “ Pareto Efficient Taxation and Expenditures: Pre- and Redistribution ,” Journal of Public Economics Special Issue in Honor of Sir Tony Atkinson (1944-2017) , 162 , pp. 101 – 119 .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. ( 2019 ), People, Power, and Profits: Progressive Capitalism for an Age of Discontent , Norton .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. , Nell Abernathy , Adam Hersh , Susan Holmberg and Mike Konczal ( 2015 ), Rewriting the Rules of the American Economy: An Agenda for Growth and Shared Prosperity , A Roosevelt Institute Book , Norton .

Stiglitz , Joseph E. , Carter Daugherty , and the Foundation for European Progressive Studies ( 2019 ), Rewriting the Rules of the European Economy: An Agenda for Growth and Shared Prosperity , Norton .

Summers , Lawrence ( 2017 ), “ Picking on robots won’t deal with job destruction ,” The Washington Post Opinion , March 5, 2017 .

Trajtenberg , Manuel ( 2019 ) “ Artificial Intelligence as the Next GPT: A Political-Economy Perspective ,” pp. 175 – 186 , in Agrawal , Ajay , Joshua Gans and Avi Goldfarb ( 2019 ), The Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda , National Bureau of Economic Research and University of Chicago Press .

Ulam , Stanislaw ( 1958 ), “ Tribute to John von Neumann ,” Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society 64 , # 3 , part 2, pp. 5 .

Varian , Hal ( 2020 ), “ Automation versus procreation (aka bots versus tots) ,” VoxEU , https://voxeu.org/article/automation-versus-procreation-aka-bots-versus-tots

Von Weizsäcker , Carl ( 1966 ), “ Tentative Notes on a Two-Sector Model with Induced Technical Progress ,” Review of Economic Studies 33 , pp. 245 – 51 .

Vinge , Vernor ( 1993 ), “ The Coming Technological Singularity: How to Survive in the Post-Human Era ,” Vision-21: Interdisciplinary Science and Engineering in the Era of Cyberspace , Geoffrey Landis , ed., NASA Publication CP-10129 , pp. 11 – 22 . https://edoras.sdsu.edu/~vinge/misc/singularity.html

Walsh , Toby ( 2016 ), “ The Singularity May Never Be Near ,” https://arxiv.org/abs/1602.06462v1 .

World Bank ( 1998 ), World Development Report 1998/1999: Knowledge for Development , Oxford University Press . https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/5981

World Commission on the Social Dimension of Globalization ( 2004 ), A Fair Globalization: Creating Opportunities for All , https://www.ilo.org/public/english/wcsdg/docs/report.pdf

World Economic Outlook (WEO) ( 2018 ), “ Manufacturing Jobs: Implications for Productivity,” Chapter 3, April 2018 .

Wu , Tim ( 2018 ), The Curse of Bigness: Antitrust in the New Gilded Age , Columbia Global Reports .

This paper is an extended version of a chapter that has been accepted for publication by Oxford University Press in the forthcoming book on “How to Achieve Inclusive Growth,” edited by V. Cerra, B. Eichengreen, A. El-Ganainy, and M. Schindler due for publication in 2021. Parts of this paper subsume ideas presented in previous work by Korinek and Stiglitz (2021a) under the title “Artificial Intelligence, Globalization, and Strategies for Economic Development.” We thank Avital Balwit, Andy Berg, Valerie Cerra, Sharmini Coorey, Romain Duval, Barry Eichengreen, Katya Klinova, Nikola Spatafora, Jeromin Zettelmeyer, participants in the IMF IG seminar series, and numerous IMF colleagues for insightful comments and suggestions; David Autor, Adrian Peralta-Alva and Agustin Roitman for helpful data and charts; and Jaime Sarmiento for excellent research assistance. Financial support from the Institute for New Economic Thinking is gratefully acknowledged.

AI is frequently defined as the ability of machines to perform tasks that previously required human intelligence. This implies that AI carries by its nature the potential to replace human labor. A number of arguments put forward in this paper are applicable not only to AI but also to other forms of technological progress.

As can be seen in the figure, the COVID shock in 2020 has clearly accelerated the trend, at least temporarily, giving rise to a large decline in employment in routine manual jobs but only a modest dip in nonroutine cognitive jobs.

See also WEO (2018) for a broader review of employment and earnings dynamics across countries and sectors.

The result is intuitive: the dual to the production function is the factor price frontier. Technological change shifts out the factor price frontier, implying that if the interest rate is unchanged, wages must increase.

One extreme example is Elon Musk’s Neuralink which aims to achieve a symbiosis of humans and AI by surgically implanting technology into the brain.

As always, calculating the full consequences of a new technology on the demand for any natural resource, or carbon emissions, is complex. It must be done on a full life-cycle basis, incorporating initial investment, maintenance, as well as day-to-day operations. That said, for instance, data centers running cutting-edge AI applications are typically energy-intensive and may lead to increases in demand for electricity and depletable natural resources. Still, on net, it is likely that the demand for carbon-based energy sources will decrease. Some natural-resource-rich economies may benefit, such as those rich in rare earths or other metals that are inputs in the production of batteries, microchips, solar panels, wind turbines etc.

In addition, many fossil-fuel-dependent countries have not yet diversified their export base, and may face limited options to diversify into job-rich manufacturing growth given this sector’s vulnerability to automation. See, e.g., Peszko et al. (2020) .

There is a large literature on the welfare economics of innovation, dating back to Arrow (1962a) . Stiglitz (1975a , 1987 ) drew attention explicitly to the public good aspects of knowledge, and the similarity between the economics of information and the economics of knowledge. See also Romer (1986) .

The inefficiencies in economies with learning by doing was first noted by Arrow (1962b) .

See Greenwald and Stiglitz (1986) . These, in turn, give rise to macroeconomic externalities, the consequences in the context of innovation have been studied by Korinek and Stiglitz (2019) .

More generally, the direction of innovation is affected by the share of the factor. If the elasticity of substitution is high, a lower factor price will be associated with an increased factor share, and this can induce greater efforts at increasing the productivity of that factor. In that case, the equilibrating force just described does not arise, and the opposite occurs ( Stiglitz, 2014 ).

As Vinge (1993) noted: “Within thirty years, we will have the technological means to create superhuman intelligence. Shortly after, the human era will be ended.” However, it should be noted that general AI does not in itself imply the singularity (e.g., Walsh, 2016 ).

Responding to Kurzweil’s (2005) thesis that “The Singularity is Near,” Walsh (2016) provides arguments for why “The Singularity May Never Be Near.”

There is even a perspective that holds that AI-powered machines could become agents of their own ( Korinek, 2019 ).

Note that this is in contrast to a long tradition in the traditional economics literature that viewed labor as an essential input for any production process.

The measurement problems are still more complicated: advertising is an “intermediate” product and does not directly enter into the value of the final goods and service that constitutes GDP. If advertising were a normal input, and markets were competitive, an increase in the efficiency of production of an intermediate good would be reflected in a lowering of the final goods price, and that in turn would be associated with an increase in GDP. Better advertising engines may, as we noted earlier, actually increase market power and decrease overall economic efficiency. Moreover, they may induce an adverse redistribution, lowering welfare still more.

Any innovations to deal with Covid-19 will still be available in the post-Covid-19 world. Moreover, the development of research strategies in response to Covid-19 may set in motion a process of “learning to learn,” learning better how to innovate in human-replacing dimensions. See Atkinson and Stiglitz (1969) and Stiglitz (1987b ).

This would not, of course, be true if the factor price equalization theorem held. More generally, differences in domestic factor ratios do not necessarily align well with differences in factor prices.

There are countervailing forces to the scarcity of labor associated with a declining working age population. A younger population may be more tech savvy, better able to pick up, adopt and adapt to new technologies. The figure suggests that the scarcity effect dominates. There are other factors too that play a role in robotization.

There is a similar dissonance between those who argue that the economy faces secular stagnation and those who say there are not the resources required for a rapid green transition.

Over the long run, the effect of the green transition on the demand for labor is more problematic. While many of the green technologies have higher upfront costs, maintenance costs are markedly lower, and not only are life-cycle carbon emissions lower, but so is labor usage.

For example, based on data for 1981–2002, Gilens (2005) finds that in the US actual policy outcomes strongly reflected the preferences of higher-income groups, with little relationship to the preferences of the poor or middle-income citizens. For a broader discussion of the interplay of economic and political inequality, see Stiglitz (2013 , 2019 ).

Harari (2017) also explores the implications of super-human artificial intelligence on society and politics.

The emphasis here is on (traded) goods rather than (non-traded) services—while learning by doing could occur in both, it is the former that drives export-led development. See, e.g., McMillan and Rodrik (2011) who note that non-traded service sector development on its own typically has not had a substantial impact on overall productivity.

Stiglitz (2015) models the relationship between technological leaders and followers.

We emphasize that the focus here is on the more adverse scenarios, to help prepare policies; should they not materialize, so much the better. We noted countervailing forces—the need for labor for the green transition, that even within advanced economies, people may still be needed for service jobs requiring physical proximity and/or the “human touch” (such as elderly care, housekeeping, etc.). Most important, these outcomes are not inevitable: we can steer innovation in a different direction and, as the discussion below will hopefully make clear, there are multiple actions that can be taken to mitigate some of the adverse effects.

Some are justifiably concerned that digital platforms are in fact very efficient at exploiting workers. But platforms can also provide information on whether workers are exploited and, with proper regulation, make it easier to address such exploitation than it used to be before the digital age.

See also Pouokam (2021) .

Some countries have started to experiment with schemes that have some characteristics of a UBI. E.g., Spain introduced in early 2020 a “minimum vital income” to ensure a guaranteed minimum income for the poorest. However, it is not unconditional, but instead tops up incomes below the minimum income, which may create disincentive effects to continue work in jobs that pay below that threshold. Several other countries have run pilot programs, often on a small scale and/or for a limited time. Overall, these programs appear to indicate that such schemes tend to have little impact on labor supply (see, e.g., https://www.vox.com/future-perfect/2020/2/19/21112570/universal-basic-income-ubi-map ). Earlier research on a negative income tax in the US suggested that by enabling individuals to search more for a better matching job may actually enhance productivity.

UBI programs may turn out to be important policies in a future in which labor truly becomes redundant ( Korinek and Juelfs, 2021 ). There is uncertainty over when that future may arise, as the earlier discussions indicated—but given the complexities of transitioning to such a new regime, there may be a rationale for countries to start experimenting with UBI systems.

Notably, some have discussed a “robot tax” that could help finance redistributive fiscal measures (e.g., Rubin, 2020 ). However, such a robot tax may be difficult to implement (e.g., what distinguishes a “robot” from traditional capital?) and may discourage innovation (e.g., Summers, 2017 ). Conceptually, government ownership of capital is equivalent to taxes on capital with exemptions on new investment that avoid any negative incentive effects of capital taxation, although it may be insufficient to provide funding for large-scale redistributive programs that may be needed in a long-term equilibrium with low employment levels. See also Korinek (2020) .

The reduced labor supply may itself help sustain higher wages.

For a broader view of how to achieve inclusivity in the labor market beyond the challenges posed by technological advances, see El-Ganainy et al. (2021) .

For example, Colmer et al. (2020) find that while fine-particle air pollution has decreased overall in the US over the past four decades, whiter and richer neighborhoods have become relatively less polluted, while poor and minority communities are (still) the most polluted.

For an extensive discussion of some of the critical “rules,” see Stiglitz et al (2015 , 2019 ). Later, we discuss a particularly important set of policies that can affect the returns to factors—those associated with steering the development and adoption of technologies.

The alternative – to allow for greater migration – would of course also put downward pressure on wages in advanced countries and might increase inequality within those countries.

Curiously, such policies have continued to be referred to as “industrial policies” even when they move the economy away from the industrial sector. We use the more generic term sectoral policies , but they are broader: they can also be used to change technology within a sector (e.g., towards green or more labor-intensive technologies).

For example, US bankruptcy provisions favoring derivatives can be thought of a sectoral policy encouraging the growth of derivatives; but until the 2008 financial crisis, few outside of that sector were even aware of the favorable treatment that derivatives have received.

In 1914, the U.S. Department of Agriculture created a system of “extension” services, with the aim of providing farmers with expert advice on agriculture and farming. See, e.g., https://www.almanac.com/cooperative-extension-services .

For a discussion of how this plays out in trade rules, see, e.g., Charlton and Stiglitz (2005) .

There is by now a large literature describing the new competition policies that may be required. See Stiglitz (2019) and Wu (2018) , as well as Akcigit et al. (2021) for an overview of emerging issues and complexities in competition policy.

It is sometimes argued that such disclosure is not possible because algorithms are always evolving. While they are always changing, they could still be disclosed as of a particular moment in time. There are other (often costly) ways of monitoring the behavior of algorithms at any point in time.

Cover IMF Working Papers

Table of Contents

  • Front Matter
  • Technological Progress, Artificial Intelligence, and Inclusive Growth
  • View raw image
  • Download Powerpoint Slide

technical progress essay

International Monetary Fund Copyright © 2010-2021. All Rights Reserved.

technical progress essay

  • [66.249.64.20|185.126.86.119]
  • 185.126.86.119

Character limit 500 /500

Technological Progress Essays

Episode creation and analysis, exploring the interplay of climate, energy and economic growth: a study of energy demand, emissions, international trade, and technological progress, popular essay topics.

  • American Dream
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Black Lives Matter
  • Bullying Essay
  • Career Goals Essay
  • Causes of the Civil War
  • Child Abusing
  • Civil Rights Movement
  • Community Service
  • Cultural Identity
  • Cyber Bullying
  • Death Penalty
  • Depression Essay
  • Domestic Violence
  • Freedom of Speech
  • Global Warming
  • Gun Control
  • Human Trafficking
  • I Believe Essay
  • Immigration
  • Importance of Education
  • Israel and Palestine Conflict
  • Leadership Essay
  • Legalizing Marijuanas
  • Mental Health
  • National Honor Society
  • Police Brutality
  • Pollution Essay
  • Racism Essay
  • Romeo and Juliet
  • Same Sex Marriages
  • Social Media
  • The Great Gatsby
  • The Yellow Wallpaper
  • Time Management
  • To Kill a Mockingbird
  • Violent Video Games
  • What Makes You Unique
  • Why I Want to Be a Nurse
  • Send us an e-mail

The Tech Trend – Next Technology Trends, News, Business Ideas

  • Machine Learning
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Software Development
  • Supply Chain Management
  • Cryptocurrency
  • Growth Strategies

Top Insights

How to write an essay on technological progress.

' src=

Technology progress is a common essay topic in almost all areas. Tutors endeavor to assess your understanding of technology application in education, space, agriculture, sports, and any study area you can imagine. You need to produce a compelling paper that will earn you top grades. You may be wondering, can someone write a college essay for me ? You can hire a professional writer to draft any paper and deliver it within hours or days.

Completing a technology progress paper requires a strategy. The plans you make will save time while ensuring that you produce the best paper. Here are a few hacks that guarantee the best essay on technology progress.

Also read: 7 Tech Gadgets That Make Daily Life Easier

Review the prompt

Technology progress is just the main subject of your essay. There are other requirements that you need to consider when writing. These requirements are captured in the prompt or instructions provided. Ensure that you understand these instructions before starting to draft your paper.

The writing prompt and instructions direct you on the structure to adopt for your essay. For instance, you may be required to compare technology growth in the past and present. The instructions may also direct you to use particular reference materials. In other cases, you receive a case study. All this information gives you an idea of the kind of essay you should produce.

The prompt is used as a checklist when grading your essay. If the structure, for instance, does not correspond with what is indicated in the prompt, you will score a poor grade. Do not waste time writing an essay that will not meet the required standards.

Read the history of technology

The topic on Technology progress hints at a review of the application of technology in the old days compared to what is used today. Read all materials on technology to give you the best perspective. Some of the materials will be on history, sociology, and anthropology.

Reading widely gives you unique ideas to discuss in your paper. You avoid pedestrian arguments, some of which cannot be substantiated. Choose high-quality and approved reference materials for your paper. It ensures that your ideas are solid and will not be discounted by other scholars soon.

Choose a specific topic

Technology progress is such a wide topic that you cannot exhaust it in a single essay paper. Choose a specific area to handle in your essay. The specific topic will be determined by your discipline of study. For instance, if you are writing a paper in medicine, your focus will be progress in the medical field. The same concept applies to education, sports, agriculture, and other disciplines.

You could also define the duration of progress. For instance, you can choose a few years, decades, centuries, and even millennia. Other areas to specify include the community using this technology like the USA, Europe, and Asia, among others. You may also focus on women or men. The aim of specifying your subject is to give the essay a scope. A reader seeing the topic will know what to expect from your work.

Develop an outline

An outline is a plan on how your ideas will appear on the paper. It indicates the points to be included in the introduction, body, and conclusion of your paper. It also captures the subtopics that will support each idea that you will discuss in the essay.

You begin developing the outline during Literature Review. At first, the ideas are haphazard, just as they emerge while you read. As you gather more points, you will identify the strongest among them so that they can appear at the top and towards the end of your paper. With ideas placed strategically within the essay, it will be compelling to read.

Hire an essay writing assistant

Hire an essay helper to write the paper on your behalf. The helpers take up some of the work like literature review or drafting once you provide an outline. In other cases, you can hire a professional to write the entire paper. Hire a qualified helper who understands the technical bits of technology. You get the assistants from the best websites that write essays for you online.

Also read: Top 10 Futuristic Technology may Come in Future

Use essay writing tools

Use essay writing tools to make your work easy. The tools include apps that help with research, organizing your reference materials, and editing your paper. Once the apps take over these peripheral activities, you can focus on drafting a captivating paper. Most of these writing tools have trial versions to help you assess their potential. Choose the right tools to avoid compromising the quality of your essay.

Allocate enough time to write and edit your paper before the submission deadline. Choose hours when your body and mind are not too tired. In this way, you produce the most insightful ideas on Technology Progress.

  • essay writing technology
  • essay writing tips
  • technology progress

' src=

Anna Johnson

Anna is a freelance writer and homework helper. She helps students to start entrepreneurship projects while in college and make money through other means. She believes that college years should be more than getting a certificate.

Leave a comment

Leave a reply cancel reply.

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Recent Posts

Modern Cybersecurity

Beyond Prevention: The Role of DDR in Modern Cybersecurity Strategies

E-Commerce Strategy

Is Your E-Commerce Strategy Missing These Crucial Elements? Find Out How to Skyrocket Your Sales

Navigating Financial Challenges

Navigating Financial Challenges: Strategies for Living Paycheck to Paycheck

Online Slot Game

How Online Slot Game Technology Has Advanced

  • Artificial Intelligence 173
  • Big Data 179
  • Blockchain 91
  • Cryptocurrency 156
  • Entertainment 85
  • Finance 293
  • Gadgets 219
  • Growth Strategies 582
  • Machine Learning 88
  • Reviews 319
  • Security 289
  • Software Development 397
  • Supply Chain Management 154
  • Wellness 96

Related Articles

Augmented Reality

Exploring the World of Augmented Reality: Applications and Future Prospects

Augmented reality (AR) has transcended the realm of science fiction, becoming an...

Wife's Instagram Messages

How Can You Track Your Wife’s Instagram Messages

From a platform for sharing photographs and stories to a place to...

OCR Document

A Complete Guide on Using OCR to Digitize Your Documents

To save, retrieve, and share information efficiently in this increasingly digital environment,...

Large PDF Compressor

Small Size, Big Impact: The Benefits of Compressed PDFs for Businesses

Businesses rely heavily on electronic documents for their daily operations. Portable Document...

institution icon

  • Unpopular Essays on Technological Progress

In this Book

Unpopular Essays on Technological Progress

  • Nicholas Rescher
  • Published by: University of Pittsburgh Press

Table of Contents

restricted access

  • Title, Copyright, Dedication
  • pp. vii-viii
  • 1. Technological Progress and Human Happiness
  • 2. The Enviromental Crisis and the Quality of Life
  • 3. The Allocation of Exotic Medical Lifesaving Therapy
  • 4. Ethical Issues Regarding the Delivery of Health Care
  • 5. Ideals, Justice, and Crime
  • 6. Economics Versus Moral Philosophy: Te Pareto Principle as a Case Study
  • 7. Why Save Endangered Species?
  • 8. Scientific Progress and the "Limits of Growth"
  • pp. 107-118
  • pp. 119-120
  • Subject Index
  • pp. 121-122

Additional Information

Project muse mission.

Project MUSE promotes the creation and dissemination of essential humanities and social science resources through collaboration with libraries, publishers, and scholars worldwide. Forged from a partnership between a university press and a library, Project MUSE is a trusted part of the academic and scholarly community it serves.

MUSE logo

2715 North Charles Street Baltimore, Maryland, USA 21218

+1 (410) 516-6989 [email protected]

©2024 Project MUSE. Produced by Johns Hopkins University Press in collaboration with The Sheridan Libraries.

Now and Always, The Trusted Content Your Research Requires

Project MUSE logo

Built on the Johns Hopkins University Campus

This website uses cookies to ensure you get the best experience on our website. Without cookies your experience may not be seamless.

Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays

Technologies are everywhere in the contemporary world. It is so due to the progress in science and all applied disciplines which provide people with more facilities in life. The world is changing due to the development of the scientific thought. That is why with the flow of time technologies became an inexplicable part of my life. In this respect I try to do my best by means of technological approach trying to implement all possible measures or devices in education, work, and entertainment. Such idea goes beyond any understanding when it touches upon the ad absurdum way of reasoning about the issue of technologies’ use for mankind.

When making a survey on my daily activities it is necessary to admit the beginning of it up to the end. The Internet resources and Web 2.0 technologies help me to communicate with friends and different communities whenever and wherever I want or need. It also considers them. Hence, after getting up I check on Facebook and MySpace status and look at possible messages from my friends living all over the world. It helps me also to communicate at once with more than one user. Then I check e-mail and comments on my blogs posted on different social networks. It helps me to share my thoughts and opinions throughout the communities of young people. The creativeness of youngster, as I see, is fully described and provided or informed via Internet resources. This is why virtual reality becomes more real.

When at college, I keep my I-Phone switched on with active silent profile in order to have SMS from fellows in neighboring classes, or for the purpose to inform somebody about a gathering. In this very device I save my photos and videos with friends and mates just to have fun and to be engaged in the process of global facilitation of nations with technological decisions. Also my I-Phone supports Wi-Fi, and it helps me to stay in touch with global community via supported services as MSN, ICQ, and Blogger. For youth it is too vital to upload some material out of the Internet and post some files in it as well. Thus, I try during a day to gather some informative materials, such as photos from parties, lunch at the refectory and kisses of couples, so that to represent these materials in the net.

Some people say that Internet and computer games do harm to the development of children and youth on the whole. Opposing to such assertion I use internet libraries and different sources for successful readings in education. It helps me to make parallels between different sayings or problems raised in classes, so that to provide personal view. Such opinion may be supposed with the relation to the Google services. Indeed, they are helpful for my educational development. For example, Google Books provides me with one of the biggest electronic libraries in the world. Moreover, there are also some materials being antique and, say, lost for centuries. Those materials which were under “Top Secret” mark are available today. Moreover, this technology saves my time because there is an appropriate fast search. So I can find any citation in a definite book.

To sum up, the world of technological progress is increasing every day. It is vital for a contemporary individual to be familiar with new technologies, because they can take more benefits then one can suppose.

Cite this paper

  • Chicago (N-B)
  • Chicago (A-D)

StudyCorgi. (2021, November 5). Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays. https://studycorgi.com/technological-progress-nowadays/

"Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays." StudyCorgi , 5 Nov. 2021, studycorgi.com/technological-progress-nowadays/.

StudyCorgi . (2021) 'Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays'. 5 November.

1. StudyCorgi . "Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays." November 5, 2021. https://studycorgi.com/technological-progress-nowadays/.

Bibliography

StudyCorgi . "Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays." November 5, 2021. https://studycorgi.com/technological-progress-nowadays/.

StudyCorgi . 2021. "Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays." November 5, 2021. https://studycorgi.com/technological-progress-nowadays/.

This paper, “Technological Progress and Technologies’ Use Nowadays”, was written and voluntary submitted to our free essay database by a straight-A student. Please ensure you properly reference the paper if you're using it to write your assignment.

Before publication, the StudyCorgi editorial team proofread and checked the paper to make sure it meets the highest standards in terms of grammar, punctuation, style, fact accuracy, copyright issues, and inclusive language. Last updated: March 24, 2022 .

If you are the author of this paper and no longer wish to have it published on StudyCorgi, request the removal . Please use the “ Donate your paper ” form to submit an essay.

Want to create or adapt books like this? Learn more about how Pressbooks supports open publishing practices.

Writing Progress Reports

Stacey Corbitt

Chapter Overview

It may seem like technical writing – indeed, many kinds of professional business writing – must be huge undertakings involving much effort and endless detail. With all the emphasis on being complete, accurate, and collaborative, do you wonder whether you can develop enough skill during college to compete as a writer in a technical or other business position? You may be hoping there’s an engineering or other professional position out there where you can stay under the radar and do your job without having to write anything important.

There is good news on this matter, and then there is great news.

First, the good news: virtually all entry-level professional positions present opportunities to practice writing in a variety of situations and for multiple types of readers. Writing in technical fields, as you may now realize, can require significant time commitment and collaboration, as well as various other “soft skills.” As a result, employees working to gain experience in the field may be tapped frequently to complete writing tasks.

Do you wonder exactly how the preceding paragraph is good news? Consider the great news: the day-to-day business of technical writing is largely short, direct reporting for specific purposes and audiences. While short reports aren’t necessarily easy to write, they do offer opportunities to practice crafting clear and concise documents. The progress report is one of several standard forms of short reports. This chapter aims to help students understand how to plan and write progress reports that meet the needs of their assignments as well as the standards of professionalism required by their fields of study and work.

What is the audience and purpose of a progress report?

Progress reports are typically requested and reviewed by one or more stakeholders in a project. Stakeholders is a general term for people who have a business interest in the subject project and may need progress reports because of fiscal, legal, financial, or other responsibility for the work in question. While progress reports may be required by the person or group at the next level of responsibility above your own, the readership and reach of your periodic progress reports can be greater than you know, sometimes applying to the top tier of an organization.

Put simply, stakeholders use progress reports to communicate about work on projects, including levels of completion and delays alike. These reports provide a number of opportunities for communication, including but not limited to

  • reporting early research findings
  • notifying stakeholders about problems
  • discussing potential changes in planned work, schedule, and other project factors
  • evaluating work completed

As with all technical writing opportunities, careful characterization of the audience and the context in which the report will be used is crucial to successfully achieving the purpose of a progress report. In addition to these standard considerations, other specific questions a writer should ask in preparation for writing a progress report include the following:

  • Has the requestor specified a form you must use? If so, do you have the most up-to-date form and specifications to follow?
  • What is the date of expected delivery for this report? What is the expected frequency of reporting? For example, do you need to report once weekly, or more or less frequently?
  • Is supporting documentation necessary? If so, how should you include it?
  • Is there an oral presentation component required with this report?
  • Have you set aside enough time to complete this report and obtain a peer review?

In a word, the key to writing efficient, clear progress reports is preparation . Always take the time needed to ask these practical questions about the rhetorical situation in which you will be writing a progress report for any project.

What is the necessary content for a progress report?

Depending upon the information you collect through the questioning activity outlined in the previous section, the specific content your project progress report will need can vary. In general, though, you might think about the content required in a progress report in a specific way: that is, part of the content comes from the past; part of it discusses the work you are doing today; and the third part of the content represents the project’s future.

Activity: begin drafting a progress report

Begin with an individual or group project in which you are currently involved, whether for your writing course or another class. Proceed by making notes in response to the following directions.

  • Next, a brief discussion of the work you are doing today or this week will address the present tense portion of your discussion.
  • Third, from the same point of view in the present moment, look ahead of you at all the project-related work you want to address between now and the next reporting milestone. Write a quick description of what plans you have for the project’s future, using the future tense to describe what you and your team will begin, what you will complete, and so on.
  • Finally, build a draft timeline that displays the entire list of tasks for your project, whether completed, ongoing, or to begin at a point in the future. You may consider developing a Gantt chart , like the one presented in Figure 11.7, shown below and adapted from Exploring Business, published by University of Minnesota (2016) .

Gantt Chart for Vermont Teddy Bear feautring the activities of cut fur, stuff and sew fur, cut material, sew clothes, embroider T-shirt, cut accessories, sew accessories, dress bears, package bears, and ship bears

Use the notes you have prepared in this activity to complete the Homework at the end of this chapter.

What are the important stylistic considerations for a progress report?

If you put yourself in the position of the typical audience for a progress report, you can identify the characteristics that are most important for that reader’s use of the document. As you know, writing that is clear, concise, complete, and correct is vital to the success of any technical document in reaching its audience and accomplishing its purpose. With regard to progress reports, particularly those written in business, one additional quality critical to success is brevity . The progress report is an ideal demonstration of writing that should include only significant details and nothing extraneous. To the extent a progress report for your work can be accomplished in one single-spaced page, do not make it longer.

Use active construction

Because they constitute a direct communication from the writer to one or more identified readers, progress reports are frequently presented in one of the common business correspondence formats: namely, an email, memo, or letter report. Correspondence is a genre of writing that lends itself to the use of personal pronouns like I , we , and you in particular. Being able to use a first-person voice with personal pronouns gives writers an advantage toward writing progress reports: personal pronouns make it easier to use active constructions.

Using the active voice, or active construction , essentially means that you construct sentences and passages in which the following characteristics are evident:

  • The subject performs the action of the verb rather than receiving the action of the verb.
  • The use of forms of “to be,” also known as state of being verbs, is minimized.
  • The emphasis of an active sentence is on the subject and verb, rather than on an object.

Consider the following examples:

Notice that the nouns first written in each sentence – my sister, the carpool, and my glasses – are all receiving the action of the verbs in the sentences.

Notice also that each of those verb phrases includes a form of to be : was bitten, is being organized, and have…been seen .

Finally, notice that the same word follows the verb phrase in each sentence – by – creating a prepositional phrase that indicates the noun or pronoun performing the action in each sentence.

Now examine the same three statements below, written in the active voice:

Notice the change in arrangement of words in each statement. You can identify the subject that appears at the beginning of each sentence; followed by the verb or verb phrase that indicates the action being performed by the subject; and finally the direct object of the sentence that receives the action of the verb. The numbers in parentheses in both sets of examples indicate the total number of words in each sentence.

What are your thoughts about converting sentence construction from passive to active for purposes of being clear in a progress report? Discuss the question with a partner in class and make some notes about your observations. Do you think the active construction has advantages over passive construction? Does active construction have disadvantages?

Near the beginning of this section, you read “… personal pronouns make it easier to use active constructions.” Do you think that statement is true? Discuss why or why not.

Stick to the facts

Your goal is to write an excellent progress report by making your work clear and complete while keeping the document brief. In the previous section, you practiced revising sentences from passive to active construction, a tactic that increases clarity while usually decreasing overall sentence length. Another useful practice in writing short reports – particularly those for the workplace – is to resist sharing your opinions, suggestions, and other unrequested content. Concentrate on reporting the facts and responding to exactly what the reader has requested.

What organizational structure should be used for a progress report?

Recall that one of your earliest tasks in preparing to write a progress report is to discover what information you must report and whether a specific form is required. In the event these details are not part of the assignment you receive, you may need to determine the clearest and most efficient way to organize the body of your report. Consider the following possibilities.

As is the case with structural considerations for any technical report, the most important point in choosing an organizational pattern is to make that pattern clear to the reader. Keep in mind that the structures delineated in the previous table are intended to guide the development of the body of your report in the event you do not receive specific guidance from the project manager or your instructor. Similarly, you may have to decide whether the report should be submitted as a letter, a memo, an email, a presentation, or another format that may be preferred by your reader.

In her 2019 book Technical Writing Essentials: Introduction to Professional Communications in the Technical Fields , author Suzan Last provides the following suggested outline of elements to include in a progress report generally (pp. 178-179):

Progress Reports: a Structural Overview

1. Introduction

Review the details of your project’s purpose, scope, and activities. The introduction may also contain the following:

  • date the project began; date the project is scheduled to be completed
  • people or organization working on the project
  • people or organization for whom the project is being done
  • overview of the contents of the progress report.

2. Project status

This section (which could have sub-sections) should give the reader a clear idea of the current status of your project.  It should review the work completed, work in progress, and work remaining to be done on the project, organized into sub-sections by time, task, or topic. These sections might include

  • Direct reference to milestones or deliverables established in previous documents related to the project
  • Timeline for when remaining work will be completed
  • Any problems encountered or issues that have arisen that might affect completion, direction, requirements, or scope.

3.  Conclusion

The final section provides an overall assessment of the current state of the project and its expected completion, usually reassuring the reader that all is going well and on schedule. It can also alert recipients to unexpected changes in direction or scope, or problems in the project that may require intervention.

4.  References section if required.

Chapter conclusion

Progress reports are an ideal example of workplace technical writing for science and engineering students to study. Progress reports represent short, clear documents with a specific purpose. These reports use typical business correspondence formats to communicate detailed technical information to a known audience. A successful progress report’s other characteristics include

  • sentences constructed in the active voice
  • factual information without opinions, speculation, or extraneous content
  • an appropriate pattern of organization

Use the notes and project schedule you prepared in the Activity earlier in this chapter to write a progress report for your current research project. Address all of the following considerations, but do not use this list to organize your report:

  • Confirm with your instructor the required report format – email, letter, memorandum, or presentation
  • Determine the appropriate organizational pattern – chronological, priority, or topic – for the body of the report
  • summarize and evaluate research findings to date
  • present the project schedule
  • problems, changes, delays, and questions

Last, S. (2019, January 1). Technical writing essentials . BCcampus OpenEd: University of Victoria. License: CC-BY-4.0 . https://pressbooks.bccampus.ca/technicalwriting

University of Minnesota. (2016, April 8). Exploring business . University of Minnesota Libraries Publishing. License: CC BY-NC-SA 4.0 . https://open.lib.umn.edu/exploringbusiness/

Mindful Technical Writing Copyright © 2020 by Stacey Corbitt is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License , except where otherwise noted.

Share This Book

Reimagining Design with Nature: ecological urbanism in Moscow

  • Reflective Essay
  • Published: 10 September 2019
  • Volume 1 , pages 233–247, ( 2019 )

Cite this article

  • Brian Mark Evans   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-1420-1682 1  

976 Accesses

2 Citations

Explore all metrics

The twenty-first century is the era when populations of cities will exceed rural communities for the first time in human history. The population growth of cities in many countries, including those in transition from planned to market economies, is putting considerable strain on ecological and natural resources. This paper examines four central issues: (a) the challenges and opportunities presented through working in jurisdictions where there are no official or established methods in place to guide regional, ecological and landscape planning and design; (b) the experience of the author’s practice—Gillespies LLP—in addressing these challenges using techniques and methods inspired by McHarg in Design with Nature in the Russian Federation in the first decade of the twenty-first century; (c) the augmentation of methods derived from Design with Nature in reference to innovations in technology since its publication and the contribution that the art of landscape painters can make to landscape analysis and interpretation; and (d) the application of this experience to the international competition and colloquium for the expansion of Moscow. The text concludes with a comment on how the application of this learning and methodological development to landscape and ecological planning and design was judged to be a central tenant of the winning design. Finally, a concluding section reflects on lessons learned and conclusions drawn.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price includes VAT (Russian Federation)

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Rent this article via DeepDyve

Institutional subscriptions

technical progress essay

Similar content being viewed by others

technical progress essay

Principles for public space design, planning to do better

Matthew Carmona

technical progress essay

Planning nature-based solutions: Principles, steps, and insights

Christian Albert, Mario Brillinger, … Barbara Schröter

technical progress essay

Acknowledgements

The landscape team from Gillespies Glasgow Studio (Steve Nelson, Graeme Pert, Joanne Walker, Rory Wilson and Chris Swan) led by the author and all our collaborators in the Capital Cities Planning Group.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Mackintosh School of Architecture, The Glasgow School of Art, 167 Renfrew Street, Glasgow, G3 6BY, UK

Brian Mark Evans

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Brian Mark Evans .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Evans, B.M. Reimagining Design with Nature: ecological urbanism in Moscow. Socio Ecol Pract Res 1 , 233–247 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42532-019-00031-5

Download citation

Received : 17 March 2019

Accepted : 13 August 2019

Published : 10 September 2019

Issue Date : October 2019

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s42532-019-00031-5

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Design With Nature
  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research
  • Share full article

Advertisement

Supported by

In Moscow’s Technological Advances, a ‘Double-Edged Sword’

The latest example is Face Pay, which replaces a Metro card with facial recognition. It may be advanced, but activists are sounding the alarm on privacy issues.

technical progress essay

By Celestine Bohlen

The Moscow Metro — a world-class marvel of efficient mass transportation since it opened in 1935 — made headlines last month with a very 21st-century innovation: a payment system that doesn’t require passengers to produce a ticket, a transit card, a smartphone or a contactless bank card. All they have to do is show their face.

By Oct. 15, the facial recognition system, called Face Pay, was up and running at about 240 stations on the Moscow Metro, a sprawling and constantly expanding system famous for its on-time track record and its grandiose and ornate stations.

Moscow city officials were quick to tout the system’s latest technological innovation, one of several over the last decade. “There are no analogues of Face Pay in terms of quality and ease of use for a passenger anywhere in the world,” said Maksim Liksutov, deputy mayor for transport.

To activate Face Pay, passengers must connect their photo with a bank card and the Metro’s Troika, or transit card, via a special mobile app. Once connected, a camera at the turnstiles identifies their faces (even with masks on) and opens the gates. In theory, it should take two to three seconds for a passenger to clear the turnstile, easing the crush of people at peak rush hours.

It is one of the most visible — and controversial — of the city’s projects to modernize its services, one that takes full advantage of advancing biometric technology and the skills of a new generation of Russian computer engineers. “The technology is new and very complex, we will continue to work on improving it,’’ said Moscow’s mayor, Sergei Sobyanin, in a statement.

But digital privacy activists in Russia were quick to raise the alarm, noting that the new system is not just about improving service on the Moscow Metro. “It is a good pretext to put cameras at the turnstiles,’’ said Artyom Koslyuk, a director at Roskomsvoboda, a digital rights group based in Moscow. “This will allow them to perfect the algorithms used for the recognition of faces.’’

According to Mr. Koslyuk, Moscow ranks third in the world for the most surveillance on streets and public transport, with some 200,000 cameras placed around the city and on the Metro to help police identify criminals and prevent crime. Russian police have already used facial recognition to find and arrest demonstrators who participated in peaceful opposition protests.

The two other countries that have gone ahead with facial recognition payment systems are China and Belarus, where privacy rights are also of little concern to the government. (In Belarus, the facial recognition system on the Minsk metro is called Look and Go.) In contrast, the European Parliament voted last month in favor of a nonbinding resolution to ban use of facial recognition technology in public places for police purposes.

Moscow officials have tried to calm concerns about privacy invasion by insisting that the images and data collected are “securely encrypted.’’ Roskomsvoboda, though, said they have uncovered evidence that the system is porous, vulnerable to intruders who can use the data and images for criminal purposes.

Privacy advocates are pushing for a more transparent system of control for this and other advanced, and often intrusive, technologies. “We need to be sure that all these innovations are used to help the people, not harm them,’’ said Mr. Koslyuk.

Face Pay is part of a broader set of efforts in the city to institute technological solutions. Moscow is undoubtedly Russia’s “smartest” city, not least because it is the nation’s capital, and a focus of government attention. Its 12.5 million people make it the second most populous city in Europe — and it is growing. Between 2002 and 2010, while Russia’s population decreased by 1.2 percent, Moscow’s grew by 10.9 percent. And the average wage in the capital is almost double the national average.

The capital also gets royal treatment from the federal government. In 2019, Moscow’s urban renewal budget equaled that of the rest of the country.

“Moscow has the power in terms of finance and budgets,’’ said Sergei Kamolov, a professor at the prestigious Moscow State Institute of International Relations. “Moscow is in the avant-garde, a test case for all different kinds of systems.’’

Two years ago, Russia adopted its own system for ranking its “smart cities,” measuring what is called their “I.Q. level.” This provides benchmarks for cities to measure progress in putting modern techniques and digital services in place for their population. Mr. Kamolov said these are useful tools to pressure local officials to meet targets set in a national “Smart Cities” program.

Mr. Kamolov, who is member of a working group on the “Smart Cities” program, cautions that its ideas and technologies are not easily duplicated from city to city. Nor, he said, do fancy new technologies necessarily have an impact on the citizens’ quality of life. “It seems to me that ‘Smart Cities’ is a deep marketing concept,’’ he said in a telephone interview.

In recent years, Russia has put a major nationwide effort into its e-government services. Ahead of the 2018 World Cup, Russia developed a system of e-visas, allowing tourists to come into the country for a limited time and for limited purpose. And like many countries, it has developed a popular online government portal — known as Gosuslugi , a one-stop website where citizens can retrieve documents, pay fines and make appointments. In a 2020 United Nations e-government survey , Russia’s services ranked 36th out of 193 countries.

In this, as in other areas, Moscow leads the way. More Muscovites use Gosuslgi proportionately than any other region of Russia — not surprising given its concentration of young, educated and computer literate people. But other regions are stepping up efforts to catch up, by offering special courses for computer literacy , especially for the elderly.

Moscow and six other regions were also used as a test case for Russia’s experiment with online voting in last September’s parliamentary elections. The system was challenged by democracy protesters, who described it as a “black box” that allowed the government to fiddle with the vote. Setting aside the contested results — a huge caveat, to be sure — online voting did its job, at least on a technical level.

Moscow has introduced other digital services in health care, in schools and in the legal system, but transportation continues to receive a hefty share of the city’s modernization budget.

According to Mr. Kamolov, Moscow has the largest fleet of electronic buses in Europe while the Metro — which now moves about six million passengers on weekdays (down from more than eight million in the pre-Covid era) — still commands a large portion of public funds: $27 billion for expansion and improvement from 2011 to 2022 , most of it for expansion but some of it undoubtedly for the facial recognition system that is now expected to be introduced in other Russian cities.

At Roskomsvoboda, Mr. Koslyuk says the key to introducing advanced digital services that depend on personal data is trust. ‘‘We need to be sure there are controls,’’ he said. “These improvements can be a double-edged sword.”

Home — Essay Samples — Geography & Travel — Travel and Tourism Industry — The History of Moscow City

test_template

The History of Moscow City

  • Categories: Russia Travel and Tourism Industry

About this sample

close

Words: 614 |

Published: Feb 12, 2019

Words: 614 | Page: 1 | 4 min read

Image of Dr. Oliver Johnson

Cite this Essay

Let us write you an essay from scratch

  • 450+ experts on 30 subjects ready to help
  • Custom essay delivered in as few as 3 hours

Get high-quality help

author

Verified writer

  • Expert in: Geography & Travel

writer

+ 120 experts online

By clicking “Check Writers’ Offers”, you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy . We’ll occasionally send you promo and account related email

No need to pay just yet!

Related Essays

6 pages / 2662 words

6 pages / 3010 words

2 pages / 1057 words

4 pages / 2143 words

Remember! This is just a sample.

You can get your custom paper by one of our expert writers.

121 writers online

Still can’t find what you need?

Browse our vast selection of original essay samples, each expertly formatted and styled

Related Essays on Travel and Tourism Industry

Travelling is a topic that has been debated for centuries, with some arguing that it is a waste of time and money, while others believe that it is an essential part of life. In this essay, I will argue that travelling is not [...]

Travelling has always been an exhilarating experience for me, and my recent trip to Rome was no exception. The ancient city, with its rich history and breathtaking architecture, left a lasting impression on me. It was a journey [...]

Traveling is an enriching experience that allows individuals to explore new cultures, meet people from different backgrounds, and broaden their perspectives. In the summer of 2019, I had the opportunity to embark on an amazing [...]

Traveling has always been a significant part of my life. From a young age, I have been fortunate enough to explore different cultures, experience new traditions, and immerse myself in the beauty of our world. My passion for [...]

When planning a business trip all aspects and decisions rely heavily on the budget set by the company for the trip. Once Sandfords have confirmed the location careful consideration should be used to choose the travel method and [...]

Place is one of the most complicated issues in geographical studies. Place refers to both sides of human and physical geography. There is not clear understand about the place and sometimes refer to local, area, point, region, [...]

Related Topics

By clicking “Send”, you agree to our Terms of service and Privacy statement . We will occasionally send you account related emails.

Where do you want us to send this sample?

By clicking “Continue”, you agree to our terms of service and privacy policy.

Be careful. This essay is not unique

This essay was donated by a student and is likely to have been used and submitted before

Download this Sample

Free samples may contain mistakes and not unique parts

Sorry, we could not paraphrase this essay. Our professional writers can rewrite it and get you a unique paper.

Please check your inbox.

We can write you a custom essay that will follow your exact instructions and meet the deadlines. Let's fix your grades together!

Get Your Personalized Essay in 3 Hours or Less!

We use cookies to personalyze your web-site experience. By continuing we’ll assume you board with our cookie policy .

  • Instructions Followed To The Letter
  • Deadlines Met At Every Stage
  • Unique And Plagiarism Free

technical progress essay

IMAGES

  1. Essay Progress Report Sample

    technical progress essay

  2. ️ Technical essay format. Importance Of Technical Writing To Students

    technical progress essay

  3. Persuasive Essay: Technical report writing pdf

    technical progress essay

  4. Technical Writing

    technical progress essay

  5. Download technical writing examples 10

    technical progress essay

  6. PPT

    technical progress essay

VIDEO

  1. write an essay on Technical Education

  2. Progress Reports

  3. Importance of technical education #essay#shorts#subscribe

  4. Technical progress and evolution

  5. Technical Education Essay

  6. Explaining the Circular Economy and How Society Can Re think Progress Animated Video Essay

COMMENTS

  1. Technological Progress Essay

    Technological Progress Essay | IT in the Last Decade. Some technological inventions have affected our life greatly for the past decades, especially computers. It's true that computers really provide us more convenient life. With computers, we can deal with many documents even faster, we can use computer to control machines to work, and we can ...

  2. The Measure technological Progress

    To effectively measure technological progress and hence render support to its relation to social progress, it is critical to understand that technology is inspired by the historical, political, social, and economic forces at play within a certain period. Anthropologists and sociologists have studied the concept of cultural and social evolution ...

  3. The long-run perspective on technological change

    New vaccines, progress in clean, low-carbon energy, better cancer treatments - a range of future innovations could very much improve our living conditions and the environment around us. But, as I argue in a series of articles, there is one technology that could even more profoundly change our world: artificial intelligence (AI).

  4. How Is Technology Changing the World, and How Should the World Change

    This growing complexity makes it more difficult than ever—and more imperative than ever—for scholars to probe how technological advancements are altering life around the world in both positive and negative ways and what social, political, and legal tools are needed to help shape the development and design of technology in beneficial directions.

  5. Technological Progress and Human Perfection Essay

    Technological Progress and Human Perfection Essay. The longer humanity exists, the more it develops technologically; moreover, in recent years, technological progress is gaining increasing speed. This process, undoubtedly, has both positive and negative sides, and Condorcet wrote about the role of progress in human life in the 19th century.

  6. 20 Most Prominent Technology Essay Topics And Writing Hints

    Stunning technology developed currently. The most shocking modern technology inventions the majority of people still aren't aware of. Enumerate some technologies that you consider completely destructive and harmful. Explain your choice. Technology and space studies. The impact of technology on people's health and values.

  7. Technological Progress, Artificial Intelligence, and Inclusive Growth

    Advances in artificial intelligence and automation have the potential to be labor-saving and to increase inequality and poverty around the globe. They also give rise to winner-takes-all dynamics that advantage highly skilled individuals and countries that are at the forefront of technological progress. We analyze the economic forces behind these developments and delineate domestic economic ...

  8. Knowledge, Technology and Complexity in Economic Growth

    In economics, it is widely accepted that technology is the key driver of economic growth of countries, regions and cities. Technological progress allows for the more efficient production of more and better goods and services, which is what prosperity depends on. However, the mechanisms through which technology is developed, adopted and used in ...

  9. Technological Progress, Artificial Intelligence, and Inclusive Growth

    However, when technological progress deteriorates the terms of trade and thus undermines the comparative advantage of entire countries, then entire nations may be worse off except if the winners within one country compensate the losers in other countries, which seems politically very difficult. ... Citation: IMF Working Papers 2021, 166; 10. ...

  10. Technological Progress Essay Examples

    Technological Progress Essays. Episode Creation and Analysis. Introduction The complex association between society and the digital world is mirrored in Black Mirror, a modern television program portraying the dark side of today's technologies. The anthology series was created by Charlie Brooker and is beyond the traditional narrative about ...

  11. How to Write an Essay on Technological Progress

    Completing a technology progress paper requires a strategy. The plans you make will save time while ensuring that you produce the best paper. Here are a few hacks that guarantee the best essay on technology progress. Also read: 7 Tech Gadgets That Make Daily Life Easier. Review the prompt. Technology progress is just the main subject of your essay.

  12. Technology and economic growth: From Robert Solow to Paul Romer

    Romer began constructing his endogenous growth theory in a pair of papers (1986, 1987), kept refining it in subsequent papers, and the work finally culminated in his 1990 paper. ... Romer's work highlights the importance of technological progress in sustaining economic growth and development. A casual observer probably can point to the ...

  13. Project MUSE

    Unpopular Essays on Technological Progress. Book. Nicholas Rescher. 1980. Published by: University of Pittsburgh Press. View. summary. Nicholas Rescher examines a number of controversial social issues using the intellectual tools of the philosopher, in an attempt to clarify some of the complexities of modern society, technology, and economics.

  14. Technological Progress and Technologies' Use Nowadays

    Words: 565 Pages: 2. Technologies are everywhere in the contemporary world. It is so due to the progress in science and all applied disciplines which provide people with more facilities in life. The world is changing due to the development of the scientific thought. That is why with the flow of time technologies became an inexplicable part of ...

  15. Writing Progress Reports

    Determine the appropriate organizational pattern - chronological, priority, or topic - for the body of the report. Include an Introduction, body, conclusion, and references (if appropriate). In the body section, address the following items: summarize and evaluate research findings to date. present the project schedule.

  16. Technical Progress

    Abstract. Over the years the term technical progress has been given a wide range of meanings and interpretations. Here we shall use the term in two main senses which will subsequently form the subject-matter of the two main sections of this Survey. First we shall use the term to refer to the effects of changes in technology, or more ...

  17. The Latest Explanation for Slow Tech Progress: Science Is Broken

    The Essay: The latest explanation for slow tech progress: science is broken. 5QQ: 5 Quick Questions for … economist Michael Strain on technological progress (part two) Micro Reads. Quote of the ...

  18. Free Essay: Technological Progress

    The first main concept that needs to be clarified is 'technology'. This paper acknowledges the concept 'technology' as being the application of science, especially to industrial or commercial objectives. The other key concept 'progress' in this essay is defined as a steady improvement, as a society or civilization.

  19. Technological progress Critique Essay (300 Words)

    Technological progress Critique Essay. When we hail to the amazing development that mankind has made in science and technology, there is a widespread concern about its negative influence on our life. In my opinion, technology is a double-edged sword, bringing about substantial benefits as well as some drawbacks.

  20. Reimagining Design with Nature: ecological urbanism in Moscow

    This essay has sought to describe the review, development and refinement process the author followed in reprising the landscape and ecological planning called for in Design with Nature augmented by the investigation and development of techniques to retain and update the essential attributes of McHarg's methods with the efficiencies of design ...

  21. In Moscow's Technological Advances, a 'Double-Edged Sword'

    The Moscow Metro — a world-class marvel of efficient mass transportation since it opened in 1935 — made headlines last month with a very 21st-century innovation: a payment system that doesn ...

  22. Full article: Urban design in underground public spaces: lessons from

    This paper examines the history and social life of the underground public spaces in three Moscow Metro stations just north of Red Square and the Kremlin: Okhotny Ryad, Tverskaya, and Ploshchad Revolyutsii stations. Moscow's subway originated from two motivations: to improve the public transit system and to revitalize Moscow's centre instead ...

  23. Policy Papers

    Capacity Development (CD), comprising technical assistance and training, fosters economic development by improving human capital and institutions in member countries. Every five years, the IMF reviews its CD Strategy to ensure that CD continues to be of high quality and well-focused on the needs of its members. This review calls for CD to become more flexible, integrated with the Fund's ...

  24. The History of Moscow City: [Essay Example], 614 words

    The History of Moscow City. Moscow is the capital and largest city of Russia as well as the. It is also the 4th largest city in the world, and is the first in size among all European cities. Moscow was founded in 1147 by Yuri Dolgoruki, a prince of the region. The town lay on important land and water trade routes, and it grew and prospered.